Modern Twists on the History of Friedman, Hayek, and Mont Pelerin
Over the weekend I reviewed here at Reason Angus Burgin's excellent new history of how free-market ideas got more libertarian over the course of the history of the Mont Pelerin Society, The Great Persuasion: Reinventing Free Markets Since the Depression.
While Burgin's book was a history, with little to say about either ideology or reality since the heyday of Milton Friedman, it had some interesting elements, and interesting lacuna, of interest to those embroiled in now-age libertarian world history and controversy as well.
One of the more interesting new developments in attempts to embed libertarian thinking in the political philosophy academy has been the self-conscious branding of many libertarian and libertarian-ish thinkers as "Bleeding Heart Libertarians," and Burgin's book provides much evidence of recent historical pedigree for that notion.
Modern bleeding heart libertarians will be buoyed, perhaps, by some details about first-generation Chicago school founder Henry Simons. Simons lamented that "we old fashioned liberals have, at best, a hard time avoiding popular classification as reactionaries" and hoped that market advocates would "talk in what is recognized to be 'progressive' language" in 1939. Simons lamented how huge corporations made arguing for economic liberalism difficult in the public eye.
Hayek, as Burgin points out, also in the early Pelerin days "found particular values in those who could speak in a language persuasive to the Left." (One wonders why believing in freer markets than one's compatriots or competitors in intellectual discourse makes you the intransigent one, as in one pungent references to Mises in Burgin.) The Pelerines in Burgin's read (not that it did them any good) "were also quick to distance their ideas from reactionary sentiment and to associate them with the forward-looking language of progressivism."
Even Milton Friedman, who Burgin paints as the radical who shifted the general Pelerin consensus toward more radical and doctrinaire laissez-faire, liked to restructure the terms of the debate over market freedom by stressing the well being of the poor and "the establishment of a broad-based prosperity." Friedman also liked to emphasize how state actions hurt the poor and uneducated, often in order to prop up the well-to-do and well-connected, and the virtues of individual choice for all, not just elites.
Still, the early Pelerines were mostly not afraid to be anti-democratic—not, as Burgin too blithely notes, because they saw freedom strictly in economic terms, but because (at least in this case) they saw freedom in freedom terms, not in terms of social decisionmaking processes for governing.
For those embroiled or fascinated by the intra-libertarian debates over who is properly hardcore and who is a sellout (always fun for those who find fun in that sort of thing), they will find outsider historian Burgin at times sounding like the most angry modern Misesian in blaming weak-tea libertarianism on a desire for more widespread appeal. Between and even sometime in the lines Burgin indicates that the Pelerines disdain for pure laissez-faire had elements more strategic than intellectual. They "were acutely aware that if they were going to persuade others to adopt their worldview, they would need to differentiate their perspective from an uncompromising adherence to laissez-faire," he notes. Walter Lippmann condemned Mises for, as Burgin concludes, being too hardcore in defense of a traditional liberalism that "did not present a viable option to those in positions of academic or political power."
And it is an interesting lacuna in Burgin's book, about the influence of the Mont Pelerin market tradition, that he never once mentions the most successful modern American politician pushing the most radical end of the larger Pelerin tradition: Ron Paul.
Friedman in a 1962 memo written to the Republican Party that Burgin quotes at length sounds like the grandfather of Ron Paul, pointing out there is out no meaningful difference between Republicans and Democrats. Burgin writes of one of Friedman's mentors in the study of social change, the British historian A.V. Dicey, and quotes Dicey sounding like he's prophesying Paul: "the preachers of truth make an impression, either directly upon the general public or upon some person of eminence, say a leading statesman, who stands in a position to impress ordinary people and thus to win the support of a nation."
Friedman himself wanted to, as Burgin wrote, "present his minority perspective in a manner that would compel members of the younger generation to adopt it as their own," and Paul succeeded at this to an extraordinary degree. It is also curious to see a book out in 2012 arguing that the Austrian strain of free-market economics remains ghettoized while "Chicago economists…assumed positions of broad political influence" without mentioning the explicitly Austrian success of Ron Paul.
To repeat what I wrote in my review, all my little arguments with Burgin are because he has achieved something excellent in the outside understanding and appreciation of the world of libertarian thought with his book, and I repeat my high recommendation of that book.
Editor's Note: As of February 29, 2024, commenting privileges on reason.com posts are limited to Reason Plus subscribers. Past commenters are grandfathered in for a temporary period. Subscribe here to preserve your ability to comment. Your Reason Plus subscription also gives you an ad-free version of reason.com, along with full access to the digital edition and archives of Reason magazine. We request that comments be civil and on-topic. We do not moderate or assume any responsibility for comments, which are owned by the readers who post them. Comments do not represent the views of reason.com or Reason Foundation. We reserve the right to delete any comment and ban commenters for any reason at any time. Comments may only be edited within 5 minutes of posting. Report abuses.
Please
to post comments
Did another Reason writer write a book?
I never get these memos.
One of the more interesting new developments in attempts to embed libertarian thinking in the political philosophy academy has been the self-conscious branding of many libertarian and libertarian-ish thinkers as "Bleeding Heart Libertarians,"
No it isn't.
Bleeding Heart Libertarians is mostly a reaction to the "fuck the poor" libertarianism that's been prevalent for the past several decades.
Bleeding Heart Libertarians is mostly a reaction to the "fuck the poor" libertarianism that's been prevalent for the past several decades
This is nothing new. Ever read Dickens? Bastiat's critics? They said the same things. The liberals that wanted to overcome the "fuck the poor" perception were the ones who created the welfare and regulatory state and the public schools in the first place!
John Rawls is also the subject of an upcoming musical; a fictionalized account of the creation of A Theory of Justice.
"Things "Bleeding Heart Libertarians" like"
Bleeding Heart Libertarians are like the Holy Roman Empire, in that it was neither holy, nor Roman, nor an empire.
Weren't classical liberals being accused of being reactionary corporate lackies over a hundred years ago? And those liberals that tried to overcome that were the socialistic ones?
Also I've never been too comfortable with the left-libertarian, BHL, fuzziness on private property. Almost like they are trying to dismiss it.
They get fuzzy on all issues of liberty when they have an inkling it won't produce a desired outcome.
You mean like "social justice" and "income equality"? The former term is quite nebulous. I'm not sure if twisting it to mean libertopia is such a good idea when generally it means more statism.
As for the latter well...um....logically wouldn't that lead to everyone having the same pay? How can that be remotely libertarian? I can see trying to eliminate pubsec unions and corporate welfare would lead to more income equality but it just as well be used to justify (as it usually is) more regulation and nationalization of industry.
Of course I can see Richman or Carson complaining about "nationalizing" industry isn't such a bad concept since in the Victorian times Lysander Spooner used that term to mean something else.
Yeah Bleeding Heart Libertarians remind me of when I explained the Nolan chart to someone. She got all excited and then said
"So if I am a libertarian on personal issues and a socialist economically, what am I?"
"A Democrat"
"No, that can't be right, I'm an independent."
Sometimes, you gotta call a spade a spade.
Actually she isn't a Democrat. Democrats aren't libertarians on personal issues, they're authoritarian on personal issues AND economic issues. Democrats are neo-fascists, your friend just sounds a bit confused.
She's an education major. So not confused so much as borderline retarded.
Spoken like a true Aborto-Freak.
the intra-libertarian debates over who is properly hardcore and who is a sellout
As one who has fun with this sort of thing i propose that Tulpa is a sellout because he voted for Romney.
I disagree. I don't think he's a sellout for voting for Romney, I understand his reasoning for that and don't think it constitutes as "selling out". I just think he's (very) wrong, and his insistence that anyone who disagrees with him is just a fool who wants to see libertarianism marginalized is incredibly obnoxious.
Now thats exactly what I am talking about dude.
http://www.ImaAnon.tk
Not sure if the folks scheduled to speak at this event in Austin would call themselves bleeding heart libertarians, but the language in the organizers' indiegogo promo seems to be an attempt to appeal to the more liberal among us.
http://www.indiegogo.com/voiceandexit