Debunking Antitrust Assumptions: More Concentration in an Industry Doesn't Necessarily Mean Higher Prices
The Biden administration's antitrust policy depends too much on the dubious belief that industrial concentration leads to higher prices.

Some ideas that animate government regulators achieve what seems like universal belief purely due to the volume of repetition. For example, many proponents of antitrust regulation believe increased concentration will increase consumer prices, even though evidence does not solidly back this up.
The theory behind why concentration in a market would lead to increased prices is so ubiquitous most people could probably recite some version of it by memory. It goes something like this: A firm without enough competitors can more or less raise prices at will; with few alternatives, consumers just have to accept the price gouging and pay up.
That claim, espoused by regulators and policy makers, can often be found alongside a similar claim about profit. The White House went so far as to say, "In an economy without adequate competition, prices and corporate profits rise, while workers' wages decrease." That tired old song has also been sung by The New York Times and the Economic Policy Institute. Most recently, this claim has led many to insist that the primary driver of the inflation we have been suffering is corporate profits, or "greedflation."
Former Clinton administration Secretary of Labor Robert Reich and others have so much faith in the "greedflation" explanation that they insist the recent inflation is caused by increased concentration over the last few decades. Underlying the claim about concentration and prices is a claim about concentration and profits, which is the cost consumers pay minus the cost of production to industry. According to greedflation logic, corporate profits indicate that concentration is leading to higher consumer prices.
The problem for proponents of this theory is that studies on corporate profits and concentration are often flawed, or sometimes even find an inverse relationship to their "concentration=inflation" narrative. Out of the studies that find relationships between markups (which are essentially another way of measuring profits) and concentration, the methodology is often flawed, focusing too much on assumptions about market structure.
The Information Technology and Innovation Foundation (ITIF) ran a series of studies on myths about monopolies, one of which focused on the claim that concentration leads to increased profits. This became particularly relevant as inflation climbed and economists searched for causes.
The ITIF study examining the relationship between profits and concentration found that nonfinancial domestic profits as a share of gross domestic product (GDP) decreased when former Secretary of Labor Reich claimed concentration had increased. Profit shares are lower today than during the 1960s when antitrust regulators were far more proactive against mergers and acquisitions. Though profits are hard to measure over entire markets, the study did not find any relationship between them and the concentration in the market.
The evidence, then, does not indicate that profits, prices, and concentration have a concrete relationship. And the theory behind why they would runs into trouble when you look at the real-world practices of some feared bigger companies. In practice, accused "monopolists" such as Amazon are not often attacked for inflating prices but for harming competition by deflating prices. That's because, in reality, large firms often have the lowest prices and markups.
The claim that consumer prices increase with concentration is far from settled fact. Yet it still has been used to block mergers under the structural presumption that they will create higher profits and prices on goods and thus harm consumers. Misinformation on the relationship between concentration and profits deprives consumers of the most efficient market, so such claims should be reexamined by antitrust policy makers in light of existing evidence.
Editor's Note: As of February 29, 2024, commenting privileges on reason.com posts are limited to Reason Plus subscribers. Past commenters are grandfathered in for a temporary period. Subscribe here to preserve your ability to comment. Your Reason Plus subscription also gives you an ad-free version of reason.com, along with full access to the digital edition and archives of Reason magazine. We request that comments be civil and on-topic. We do not moderate or assume any responsibility for comments, which are owned by the readers who post them. Comments do not represent the views of reason.com or Reason Foundation. We reserve the right to delete any comment and ban commenters for any reason at any time. Comments may only be edited within 5 minutes of posting. Report abuses.
Please
to post comments
The claim that consumer prices increase with concentration is far from settled fact.
The people who claim this are usually mad about profits, not prices.
Profits are the price we pay for efficiency. Concentration increases efficiency which increases profits. As long as they keep their price low enough to make competitors unprofitable, they’re increasing profits and lowering prices at the same time. Sounds like breaking a law of physics.
I think what happens is the complainers see the profits and assume that they were a result of higher prices, not efficiency.
I've also noticed lot of complainers seem to confuse revenue with profits.
I’m talking about increasing profits with efficiency while also lowering prices to keep out the competition. The losers are the competition. Everyone else wins.
edit: before long someone will outsmart the big guy with some new idea. wash rinse repeat. but these laws are always designed to protect the competition while claiming to protect the consumer, who benefits from the concentration and increased efficiency and increases profits.
someone appeals to envy with "Look at those record profits! You're getting ripped off!"
no, that means the opposite.
Yes I know what you are talking about, I'm just adding that sometimes the people mad about profits aren't even looking at profits, they are looking at revenue (which can still go up even as profits are flat, down, or even negative)
Most of us understood you were agreeing and expanding. Have to ignore sarcs victim complex.
I'm making over $7k a month working component time. I saved hearing other people inform me how lots cash they could make online so Qd I decided to look at it. Well, it turned into all proper and has definitely modified my life. Get this today by..
Follow instructions —>>> http://Www.Bizwork1.com
Oh, ok. Fair enough.
edit: Right, when they say Exon made blah blah blah.
The focus on prices is an example of misdirection. Even if it were true that lack of competition invariably causes higher prices it does not justify the government intervening in any way. Even if you could somehow imagine a commodity that was so essential to life that paying a higher price to obtain it was unavoidable, people would pay that price and do without something less urgent in order to afford it. Fairness should NEVER be a justification for government interference in the market. Since that is simply an imaginary scenario and could never happen in the real world except as a temporary emergency in a catastrophic event, the more realistic question that they don't want you to ask is, "So what if the price of gizmos goes up? Won't someone else come along and make a better product at a lower price and take the monopoly away? Why do I need the government saying whether Amazon can buy out RoboSuck?"
Don’t they use profits as evidence of high prices?
edit: and profits are by definition unfair, being the excess labor that capitalists steal from the working class. Pardon the sarcastic marxism.
But if the government has already created regulatory barriers that prevent the someone else from ever marketing the better product, then of course the government must step in to fix the monopolist exploitation by incumbents. The only possible solution to a government screw-up is more government.
That is, of course, true. But it just pushes back the argument to government intervening in the market at a different point in the process. If government intervention in the market creates monopolies, for example. Or government intervention in the market protects copyrights, trademarks or patents. Or government limits the liability of investors in a corporation.
I always figured that antitrust laws were used when the wrong company got a corner on the market.
Let's get real here. Anti-trust is like the nanny of [Na]tional So[zi]al[ism] where irresponsible concentration gets bailed out without consequence when they go belly-up.
So I for one; Am not going to speak out against Anti-trust law until the Nazi-Subsidies stop.
Monopolies are dangerous, but they are not inherently evil. The evil is protectionism whether expressed through cronyism or tariffs.
Jeff Bezos said, famously, "Your margin is my opportunity". Monopolists will be tempted to increase prices. The more they do so, the greater the opportunity for new entrants to undercut and disrupt them. Only when the government blocks competitors from innovation, business formation, or scale-up, do the monopolists enjoy unjustified economic rents. Such monopolists become thugs and goons, as we have seen in US history and in countries such as Russia today.
The worst monopoly pricing occurs when government enforces the monopoly. Drugs and medical devices sold in the USA are protected from competition by patents and by FDA regulation. The patents run out in 20 years - which is often less than 10 years by the time the maker gets FDA approval to market the drug - but often the FDA allows a company to reformulate their drug when the patent expires, get a new patent good for another 20 years, and have FDA ban other companies from selling the original drug because the first company withdrew it from the market. Then it's not uncommon to see outrageous profit margins, not when the inventors need to recoup the costs of development and FDA approval, but when the FDA maintains the monopoly for decades after the patent expired.
But if the "monopoly" occurs only because of concentration, that is, one company outsells all the rest, price-gouging will bring competition and lower prices, while low pricing may preserve a free-market monopoly. Microsoft has maintained a near monopoly on small computer operating systems for decades, but only by selling DOS and then Windows for low prices. Because of Microsoft's size, no one else can develop a directly competitive operating and sell it for so little without going broke.
For decades, competitors were successful only in 3 niche markets: Apple, which caters to users that don't want to learn anything about their computers; Unix servers and mainframes, where software is installed and maintained by professionals for applications far more heavy-duty than Windows was ever designed to handle (but it still sells into this market somehow); and Linux, which is nearly free for tech-savvy hobbyists that don't mind studying the manuals long after Windows and Apple users finished the job and moved on.
Their largest competitor now is the Android operating systems, which undersells Windows and serves users even more naive than Apple users. Mostly it runs "devices" for those that don't even want to know that their cell-phone, tablet, or music player is a computer. That's not so much a break in Microsoft's market monopoly as proof that one thing cannot cover all needs. I've seen Swiss Army knives two or three inches thick; they do everything, but are awkward when I just need to cut a string!