What the 1970s Can Teach Us About Today's Inflationary Politics
Inflation is a problem for politicians. Unfortunately for them, it's not a problem they know how to solve.

Ronald Reagan won the 1980 presidential election for many reasons—energy woes, taxes and regulations, crises in Iran and Afghanistan, discomfort with the sexual revolution, a vague yet unmistakeable "crisis of confidence" that Reagan's Democratic rival, President Jimmy Carter, infamously described in his 1979 "malaise" speech. But all that took second place to a single, highly specific metric: inflation.
By October 1979, Americans agreed by an overwhelming margin that inflation was the most important issue facing the country. A New York Times/CBS News poll found that 40 percent of the country named it as their top concern, more than twice the number that picked the next biggest concern, energy. That 40 percent figure arguably understated the public's sense of alarm: Another 20 percent said inflation was an important problem (if not the most important), and 8 percent said the nation's biggest issue was "the economy," which could easily cover concerns about stagnant wages and rising prices. Even those who named "energy" were likely worried about supply constraints and spiraling costs.
It's not hard to understand why Americans were so concerned. Inflation, as measured by the Consumer Price Index, hit 13.3 percent in 1979, its highest level in more than three decades. In 1980, that figure came in at an only-slightly-reduced 12.4 percent. All of this came in the context of a decade that saw dramatically slower overall economic growth than in the previous two decades, and a substantial reduction in typical family income, even as two-earner households became more common with the mass entry of women into the workforce. Inflation was eating into family earnings, to the point where some were making more on paper yet found themselves with reduced buying power.
By summer 1979, the vast majority of Americans (84 percent) told Gallup that the country was on the wrong track. Inflation was the single metric by which the country's failures and foibles could be measured. It was the country's most pressing problem. The question was what the next president was going to do about it.
American politicians had tried to control inflation before. The presidents and power brokers of the 1970s had tried price controls, public campaigns, pressure programs, blame games, and attempts to redefine basic economic terminology. The parties differed on the specifics, but both seemed to agree that the voting public and the private sector were to blame, not the bureaucrats and politicians in charge.
Inflation, in short, was a political problem, in the sense that it caused problems for politicians. But it wasn't one America's politicians knew how to solve.
On the contrary, America's political class had spent the '70s failing to fix inflation, or actively making it worse, often with policies designed to address other political and economic problems. That decade's price hikes were prolonged and exacerbated by political decisions born of short-term thinking, outright cowardice, and technocratic hubris about policy makers' ability to enact sweeping changes and manage the macroeconomy.
Now, more than 40 years later, it's (kind of, sort of) happening again.
We Were All Keynesians Then
Inflation came to a head as a political issue in 1980, but the story began more than a decade earlier. The spirit of that era was captured in a December 1965 cover story for Time, dedicated to the economist John Maynard Keynes. After declaring in its title that "We are all Keynesians now," Time touted the near-total domination of Keynes' theories of macroeconomic management.
Keynes was initially thought of as "little but a left-wing mischief maker," Time reported, but by the mid-1960s his ideas had "been so widely accepted that they constitute both the new orthodoxy in the universities and the touchstone of economic management in Washington. They have led to a greater degree of government involvement in the nation's economy than ever before in time of general peace." The story went on to quote White House budget director Charles L. Schultze, who said, "We can't prevent every little wiggle in the economic cycle, but we now can prevent a major slide." The economy, in the view of many Washington power brokers, had been solved. Such was the confidence of the age.
Schultze was first appointed as a deputy in the White House budget office by President John F. Kennedy in 1962, and he would later serve as President Lyndon B. Johnson's budget chief as well as Carter's top economic adviser, creating a continuity of policy between nearly two decades of Democratic administrations.
Johnson was the Oval Office architect of what became known as the Great Society, explicitly portrayed as a sequel-in-spirit to the New Deal of the 1930s. In addition to the health care programs Medicare and Medicaid, the Great Society featured a bundle of programs designed to lift up the poor, which Johnson dubbed the War on Poverty. Kennedy had already embarked on an anti-poverty initiative, structured as a 10-city demonstration program. But Johnson wanted more than a series of pilots.
In his memoir, The Vantage Point, Johnson wrote of his dissatisfaction with that narrower approach. He was determined to "not start small." Instead, his program "had to be big and bold and hit the whole nation with real impact.…I didn't want to paste together a lot of existing approaches. I wanted original, inspiring ideas." Johnson exploited the nation's grief over the assassination of Kennedy to advance and expand a government-centric liberal agenda. And thus, historian Steven F. Hayward notes in The Age of Reagan: The Fall of the Old Liberal Order, the "cautious, incremental approach of the demonstration project was swept aside in favor of a mad dash to an immediate national program." Bigger programs were better programs, not because there was any evidence that bigger was better, but because bigger programs were an end unto themselves.
It wasn't so much that the War on Poverty itself drove inflation, but Johnson's unchecked ambitions for new federal programs and economic intervention set the stage for the economic turmoil of the 1970s. His desire for "big and bold" federal programs summed up the policy hubris that ran through the political establishment, especially but not only among liberals.
By far the biggest components of the Great Society were the health care programs, Medicare and Medicaid, which swiftly outpaced their initial spending projections and coincided with rapid expansions of health care spending in the economy. Before Medicare and Medicaid began in 1966, health care spending as a share of the economy had held steady at around 5 percent of GDP. By 1980, that figure was nearly 9 percent and rising quickly. Overall federal spending exploded in the late 1960s, growing at double-digit rates most years, partly because of Great Society spending and partly due to the escalating costs of the war in Vietnam.
Most economists and politicians of the era misunderstood the causes of inflation. As inflation began to tick up in the late 1960s, Johnson's Council of Economic Advisers blamed monopolies; their solutions were a mix of antitrust and bully-pulpit pressure. Johnson employed a tactic that came to be called "jawboning," which Time, comparing Johnson's approach with Nixon's, described in 1969 as involving "White House pressure on specific industries against specific price increases."
President Richard Nixon also pressured business to hold down prices and wages, but the inflation rate continued to climb. In 1965, Nixon had insisted that "the lesson that government price fixing doesn't work is never learned," and during his presidential campaign he promised he would "not take this nation down the road of wage and price controls." But when inflation hit 6 percent in 1971, that's exactly what he did.
In August 1971, Nixon delivered a prime-time speech in which he announced that he was officially "ordering a freeze on all prices and wages throughout the United States for a period of 90 days" and appointing "a Cost of Living Council within the government" tasked with working "with leaders of labor and business to set up the proper mechanism for achieving continued price and wage stability after the 90-day freeze is over."
It was a transparently political move designed to counter the widespread sense that his economic plan consisted of simply doing nothing about inflation. That perception had cost Republicans a dozen House seats in Congress in the 1970 midterm election, and Nixon was no doubt well aware of the toll that inflation could take on a politician's fortunes. Thus, Nixon's Executive Order 11615 called for the establishment of a Pay Board and a Price Commission to manage the economy following the initial 90-day freeze, with the goal of eventually lifting the control—after the next election. The price controls were popular at the time, and Nixon won reelection in 1972, but the price increases didn't stop.
Undeterred, Nixon briefly reinstated a freeze on prices in 1973. Not only did he fail to learn the lesson that price controls don't work, he made the same mistake twice.
After Nixon resigned following the Watergate scandal, his successor, Gerald Ford, resorted to jawboning voters, pleading with them to "whip inflation now," or "WIN" by cutting their expenses, living a little more frugally, and wearing catchphrase-printed pins on their lapels. Inflation, apparently, could not possibly have been the fault of politicians or policy makers. It had to be someone else. For Johnson, the culprit was corporations. For Nixon, it was employers paying unapproved wages. For Ford, it was the voters themselves.
By the time Carter became president, inflation so bedeviled the administration's fortunes that it produced sentences from American officialdom like this one: "Between 1973 and 1975 we had the deepest banana that we had in 35 years, and yet inflation dipped only very briefly."
Banana was the word that Alfred Kahn, the top economist on Carter's inflation task force, had taken to using instead of recession. Despite Nixon's price controls and Ford's WIN campaign, prices had surged throughout the decade. Under Carter, they spiked yet higher.
When Carter eventually faced Reagan in a head-to-head debate, just days before the 1980 election, the issue inevitably arose. Carter was asked about the rapid rise in inflation during his tenure, with increases in the Consumer Price Index jumping from 4.8 percent in 1976 to more than 12 percent in 1980. "Can inflation," the moderator wondered, "in fact be controlled?"
Carter dodged and deflected, blaming OPEC for raising oil prices and defending his lackluster economy on the grounds that "the recession that resulted this time was the briefest we've had since the Second World War." Plus, he said, job creation was strong, with 9 million new jobs. He insisted that Reagan's plan to cut income taxes could result in a 30 percent inflation rate. And, in a follow-up, he returned to the old idea that it was the economic indulgences of the American people that were most relevant to rising prices. "We have demanded that the American people sacrifice," he said.
When Reagan got a chance to answer a version of the same question, he flipped Carter's response: "I think this idea that has been spawned here in our country, that inflation somehow came upon us like a plague and therefore it's uncontrollable and no one can do anything about it, is entirely spurious," he said. He noted Carter's broken promises on the economy, cited the millions of Americans still out of work, and rebuked the president for trying to escape blame. Carter, Reagan said, had blamed "the people for inflation, OPEC, he's blamed the Federal Reserve System, he has blamed the lack of productivity of the American people, he has then accused the people of living too well and that we must share in scarcity, we must sacrifice and get used to doing with less. We don't have inflation because the people are living too well. We have inflation because the government is living too well."
Reagan may not have been correct about every specific claim he made in that exchange, but it hardly mattered. He had highlighted the fecklessness of Carter—and, by implication, the past decade and a half of American presidents—on inflation. Faced with public anger over rising prices, they had blithely treated macroeconomic management as a solved problem, run up federal spending on ambitious social welfare programs, and deployed marketing gimmicks and economic controls they should have known would fail to resolve the underlying problem. In their self-centered hubris, in their refusal to admit that government could be the source of economic problems rather than the solution, they paved the way for Reagan's presidency.
The conservative policy realignment that Reagan ushered in—on taxes, military spending, foreign policy, and more—was thus a product of inflation. That inflation was in large part a product of a decade and a half of liberal overreach.
Choosing Inflation
The clearest error in Reagan's retort to Carter was in his invocation of the Federal Reserve. Carter had, at times, blamed the central bank for inflation. But in that case, Carter wasn't simply deflecting. Through the 1960s and the 1970s, economic policy makers had believed there was a direct tradeoff between unemployment and inflation—and they had expressed a preference for inflation if it meant keeping unemployment down.
In the early 1960s, a pair of Nobel Prize–winning economists, Paul Samuelson and Robert Solow, argued that in order to keep unemployment around 3 percent, U.S. policy makers should be willing to accept that "the price index might have to rise by as much as 4 to 5 percent a year. That much price rise would seem to be the necessary cost of high employment." Both economists were close to Kennedy, who pushed for low interest rates, hoping to spur rapid economic growth.
This approach was passed on to successive administrations. By 1971, reeling from political backlash to a recession, Nixon reportedly said, "We'll take inflation if necessary, but we can't take unemployment," according to William Greider's 1987 book Secrets of the Temple.
Nixon, too, made it known that he wanted cheap interest rates and easy money, pressuring his newly installed Fed chief, Arthur Burns, to follow through. In 1971, he said that "what we're going to do first is have an expansionary budget," according to David Frum's 2000 book How We Got Here. "We also, according to Dr. Arthur Burns, will have an expansionary monetary policy, and that will, of course, be a monetary policy adequate to meet the needs of an expanding economy." And from December 1971 to December 1972, the country's money supply grew precipitously, from $228 billion to $249 billion. Nixon's economic plans were never secret or hidden. He wanted more federal spending, and the grease of expansionary monetary policy came from the Federal Reserve.
Another Nobel Prize–winning economist, Milton Friedman, famously said that "Inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon, in the sense that it is and can be produced only by a more rapid increase in the quantity of money than in output." One might quibble that declines in supply can produce the same effect, even if the money supply stays constant. But the principle is sound. The causes of inflation may be complex and multitudinous, but they boil down to too much money chasing too few goods.
In the 1970s, that is exactly what happened in the American economy, often by design. As Frum wrote, "The United States had consciously chosen to inflate its currency. It made that choice because of the political ideology and personal weakness of the men entrusted with the job of managing the American economy: their utopianism, their arrogance, and then finally their cowardice."
The inflation that vaulted Reagan into office was not an accident or an incidental effect of policy. It was the result of deliberate policy choices.
Inflation Returns
In late January 2021, just days after President Joe Biden was sworn into office, The New York Times published an article whose headline declared that the new president was pursuing "the biggest stimulus in history."
The details were still coming together, the Times noted, but the plan's backers were more focused on headline numbers than policy specifics. They wanted a spending package that was big, almost independent of what was in it. "It's better to err on the side of too much rather than too little," Moody's Analytics Chief Economist Mark Zandi told the Times. "Interest rates are at zero, inflation is low, unemployment is high. You don't need a textbook to know this is when you push on the fiscal accelerator."
Biden echoed this line in his pitch for the bill, which quickly came together as a $1.9 trillion package dubbed the American Rescue Plan. "Let me be clear," he tweeted in February 2021. "The risk in this moment isn't that we do too much—it's that we don't do enough. Congress must pass the American Rescue Plan to change the course of this pandemic and start our economic recovery."
Critics, including some economists associated with the Democratic Party, warned that Biden's determination to go big could set off an inflationary spiral. Among the most prominent of those critics was Harvard economist Lawrence Summers, a former adviser to President Barack Obama, who in February 2021 wrote in The Washington Post that "while there are enormous uncertainties, there is a chance that macroeconomic stimulus on a scale closer to World War II levels than normal recession levels will set off inflationary pressures of a kind we have not seen in a generation, with consequences for the value of the dollar and financial stability."
Biden ignored Summers' call for a substantially smaller bill. The president flatly rejected a Republican counteroffer that would have cut the bill's cost to about $600 billion in more narrowly targeted pandemic relief. He offered no substantial criticism of the idea; he simply objected that it was too small.
There was no risk in overreach. The only danger was in doing too little.
This attitude was in many ways a holdover from the 2007–'08 financial crisis and the Great Recession that followed. The prevailing sense among many economists, pundits, and politicians on the left was that despite passing a nearly $900 billion stimulus package shortly after taking office—the largest ever at the time—the Obama administration had been too cautious and conservative in its response. The Federal Reserve had effectively lowered interest rates to zero and held them there for more than a decade, and it had expanded the money supply through multiple rounds of monetary stimulus called "quantitative easing." Yet they felt the Great Recession dragged on for so long because that historically large response was insufficient. This time would be different. There would be no such timidity. As that January 2021 Times article said, "Supporters of a 'hot' economy see a chance to correct the mistakes of the last recession."
Under Obama, Democrats had not only passed a sweeping stimulus plan; they had pushed through the Affordable Care Act, the largest single expansion of federal social spending in decades. And they had increased the federal government's regulatory oversight in myriad ways, especially regarding the environment. Obama had often described his legislative achievements as middle-of-the-road compromises, but they were nothing if not ambitious.
And then there was President Donald Trump, who throughout his presidency publicly pressured the Federal Reserve to keep interest rates low and to keep pursuing bond-buying monetary expansions. "We have the potential to go up like a rocket if we did some lowering of rates, like one point, and some quantitative easing," Trump tweeted in April 2019. "Yes, we are doing very well at 3.2% GDP, but with our wonderfully low inflation, we could be setting major records &, at the same time, make our National Debt start to look small!" Inflation was low, in other words, so there was no real risk to stepping on the gas. Why not push the economy even harder? Even before Biden stepped into the Oval Office, Trump wanted to run the economy hot.
When the COVID-19 pandemic set in, Congress passed and Trump signed the CARES Act, the largest fiscal stimulus in history. Combined with several follow-up packages, pandemic relief spending ultimately totaled about $6 trillion, all deficit-financed. Among those bills' provisions were checks of up to $1,200 per adult and $500 per child for most households in the country, $800 billion in forgivable loan programs for businesses, and a new federal unemployment benefit so large that many beneficiaries actually earned more being out of work than they had while employed. The Trump and Biden administrations took other actions, including suspending the repayment of student loans and temporarily prohibiting evictions for people who failed to pay rent. The American Rescue Plan passed under Biden included a temporary program of monthly checks doled out to the vast majority of American parents.
So even as a pandemic and associated restrictions on business activity wreaked havoc on the economy, American bank accounts swelled. From March 2020 to January 2022, according to the Brookings Institution, American households socked away $2.5 trillion in "excess savings," mostly in the form of bank deposits. Some of this was due to the circumstances of the pandemic, which depressed spending on travel and eating out. But much of it was a direct result of policies that showered easy cash on American households. "Although labor-market income was quite weak early in the pandemic," the Brookings report says, "federal benefits more than compensated overall."
Americans were flush with cash and stuck at home. So they bought stuff. Couches, vinyl records, large televisions, large bottles of whiskey, webcams, desk chairs, sweatpants, clothes that weren't sweatpants but somehow felt like sweatpants—anything that would make an extended stay at home more comfortable was suddenly a hot commodity. Good luck finding a new video game console at the $500 retail price: On eBay, PlayStation 5 consoles regularly sold for over $1,000.
And people bought food. So much food. During the early days of the pandemic, grocery store shelves were bare; meat, especially, was difficult to find. The worst shortages were mostly resolved within a few months, but prices for in-demand items marched steadily upward and some supply issues persisted. By summer 2021, it was so difficult to find chicken wings that Wingstop, a chicken wing chain, launched Thighstop, a new brand intended to move consumers away from their core product.
Pandemic-era labor costs and supply-chain kinks contributed to the problems, but demand for durable goods and home-cooked food had gone through the roof. Despite the unprecedented circumstances of the pandemic, this was a classic, practically textbook inflationary scenario. Too much money was chasing too few goods.
Prices began to rise.
Days of Deflection
At first, the Biden administration dismissed concerns about inflation, arguing that it would be "temporary." In June 2021, as the annual inflation rate ticked up to 5.4 percent, Biden said, "Our experts believe, and the data shows, that most of the price increases we've seen were expected and expected to be temporary."
But prices kept rising. In December, after the year-over-year rate hit 6.8 percent, Biden admitted that inflation was a "real bump in the road" but also predicted that the economy had reached the "peak of the crisis." It hadn't. Prices rose every month for more than a year. In June 2022, the annual inflation rate hit 9.1 percent, the highest since November 1981.
As prices continued to soar, Biden and his allies stopped insisting it would be temporary. Instead they said it wasn't their fault. In late 2021, then–White House Press Secretary Jen Psaki said that the "root cause" was the pandemic. Sen. Elizabeth Warren (D–Mass.), following a cohort of left-leaning policy activists, blamed greedy corporations "exploiting the pandemic to raise prices on everyday essentials." In late 2021, The New York Times reported that "as rising inflation threatens his presidency, President Biden is turning to the federal government's antitrust authorities to try to tame red-hot price increases." The president didn't blame OPEC, but when Russia invaded Ukraine in 2022, the Biden administration found its own foreign culprit: Inflation became "Putin's price hike."
In Congress and in the media, talk of price controls returned. In August 2022, Rep. Jamaal Bowman (D–N.Y.) introduced the Emergency Price Stabilization Act, which calls for the federal government to "build the capacity to establish limits on the growth of certain prices, and to otherwise strategically regulate such prices, in order to stabilize the cost of essential goods and services." A Princeton historian and an Amherst economist argued in The Washington Post that World War II–era price controls were a "total success" and that targeted price caps could effectively fight inflation again.
Biden congratulated himself when a Bureau of Labor Statistics report showed that there was no overall inflation for the single month of July 2022: "I just want to say a number: zero. Today, we received news that our economy had zero inflation in the month of July. Zero percent," Biden said in August. The same report showed the year-over-year inflation rate—the most common way of discussing inflation data—at 8.5 percent.
Once again, there was talk of a recession. At the end of July, the Bureau of Economic Analysis released preliminary data showing two consecutive quarters of negative growth, a common colloquial definition of a recession. Recessions are formally determined, though, by a small, secretive group of economists at the National Bureau of Economic Research, who often wait months or years to announce that one is happening or has happened. On social media, there were endless pedantic debates about whether or not to use the "r" word. The economy was in a technical mystery state; it had become a sort of Schrödinger's banana.
Biden declared early in 2022 that fighting inflation would be his top priority, but declined to take straightforward steps to do so. The Peterson Institute for International Economics estimated that a package of tariff reductions could reduce one measure of inflation by 1.3 percentage points, leaving a typical U.S. household with an additional $797, but Biden resisted calls to reduce costly trade barriers.
Instead, his inflation-fighting commitment mostly turned out to mean he'd rebrand his familiar economic agenda as a set of inflation-fighting tools. In August, Congress passed and Biden signed the Inflation Reduction Act, a package of climate and health care spending programs paired with a corporate tax hike. It was essentially a scaled-down version of the "Build Back Better" plan that Biden had pursued the previous year, when inflation hadn't been a priority.
Despite its name, there was little reason to expect the law to have much impact on inflation, especially in the short term. Analysts at the Penn Wharton Budget Model, a macroeconomic simulator often used to extrapolate the effects of federal policy, concluded that "the Act would have no meaningful effect on inflation in the near term." At best, it might reduce inflation by 0.1 percentage points several years after enactment, and even that was in doubt. "These point estimates," the authors concluded, "are not statistically different from zero, indicating a low level of confidence that the legislation would have any measurable impact on inflation." Similarly, analysts at JPMorgan Chase said the law would have "almost no effect" on the expected growth in prices.
The White House's position was that the bill would help struggling families by making drugs, health insurance, and energy more affordable. The bill included a system of de facto price controls for drugs in Medicare; extended subsidies for individual market health insurance under Obamacare, the biggest benefit of which would go to six-figure earners; and various subsidies and tax credits designed to promote green energy, including an electric vehicle subsidy that, thanks to various "Buy American" rules, would apply to no vehicles now on the market.
In short, the bill was supposed to fight inflation by hiding the true cost of goods and services through federal subsidies and price regulations. Maybe Nixon was right after all: "The lesson that government price fixing doesn't work is never learned."
This Is the Remix
If Democrats perform poorly in the November midterms or Biden loses the 2024 presidential election, it will be because of a complex array of reasons, some political, some social, some economic, some psychological, some within Biden's power to affect, some totally beyond his control. But as in 1980, all of those issues will probably take second place to a single specific metric, one that in its way serves as a catch-all for all the others.
Controversies over shifting racial norms dominate social and political discourse. Youth-driven trends in sexual identification and behavior have left many upset and unsettled. Trust in institutions is at an all-time low. There is a prevailing sense of apocalypticism: Books and op-ed pages regularly raise the prospect of a new civil war. In June 2022, Gallup reported that 87 percent of Americans believe the country is on the wrong track. America is once again facing a crisis of confidence.
And once again, polls show that rising prices top all other priorities for voters.
Is America of 2022 simply repeating the mistakes of the 1960s and 1970s? It isn't a note-for-note remake, but it does feel rather like a remix, a collage of historically familiar elements rearranged and repackaged in an updated aesthetic. If there is a lesson to be learned from the inflationary drama of the recent past, it is that inflation is to some degree a policy choice, made for political reasons. And thus, as with Reagan in the 1980s, it has both policy and political consequences.
This time, however, the next Republican presidential nominee won't be Reagan. The resulting political and policy revolution, whatever form it takes, will almost certainly be one that Biden and his fellow Democrats find far from agreeable. When they object, it will be worth remembering: They chose this path. They were warned. And they have no one to blame but themselves.
This article originally appeared in print under the headline "Inflation, Remixed."
Editor's Note: As of February 29, 2024, commenting privileges on reason.com posts are limited to Reason Plus subscribers. Past commenters are grandfathered in for a temporary period. Subscribe here to preserve your ability to comment. Your Reason Plus subscription also gives you an ad-free version of reason.com, along with full access to the digital edition and archives of Reason magazine. We request that comments be civil and on-topic. We do not moderate or assume any responsibility for comments, which are owned by the readers who post them. Comments do not represent the views of reason.com or Reason Foundation. We reserve the right to delete any comment and ban commenters for any reason at any time. Comments may only be edited within 5 minutes of posting. Report abuses.
Please
to post comments
I am making 80 US dollars per hr. to complete some internet services from home. I did not ever think it would even be achievable , however my confidant mate got $13k only in four weeks, easily doing this best assignment and also she convinced me to avail.
For more detail visit this site.. http://www.Profit97.com
After leaving my previous job 12 months ago, i’ve had some good luck to learn about this website which was a life-saver for me.They offer jobs for which people can work online from their house. My latest paycheck after working for them for 4 months was for $4500.Amazing thing about is that the only thing required is simple typing skills and access to internet.
Read all about it here……..>>> OnlineCareer1
Great article, Mike. I appreciate your work, I’m now creating over $35400 dollars each month simply by doing a simple job online! I do know You currently making a (ad-10) lot of greenbacks online from $28000 dollars, its simple online operating jobs
Just open the link——————–>>> https://googlejob26.blogspot.com
This is strong analysis but I'm disappointed in his omitting Modern Monetary Theory. MMT is a Lysenkoist corruption of economics by economists whose first loyalty is to leftist politics rather than economic reality. There was never any supporting evidence for it, the entire theory evolved from what I call Debate Reality where people assert whatever helps their debate as reality regardless of whether there is anything to support it. Activist "economists" like Krugman know the left's control of media and academia ensure they will never pay a price for this Lysenkoism so they feel free to support their activism with this version of Voodoo Economics.
All this ties back to the Carter years with so called experts denying reality in support of political goals. The key takeaway from the comparison from the 70s to now is how much clearer this is corruption rather than hubristic error.
>Debate Reality
Excellent term. We need one for that sort of skewed perspective.
Great article, Mike. I appreciate your work, I’m now creating over $35400 dollars each month simply by doing a simple job online! I do know You currently making a (ad-09) lot of greenbacks online from $28000 dollars, its simple online operating jobs
Just open the link——————–>>> https://smart.online100.workers.dev/
There are countries in Europe where inflation is worse so that means Americans are in no position to complain about it. What really matters is that rig count is up. The Biden economy is fantastic.
#TemporarilyFillingInForButtplug
You know where a buttplug goes, right?
Into a butt jack?
Into a butt, Jackie? Where?
Into Jackie's butt. Even Kennedy was shocked.
I think OBL is well aware.
In 1983 we built a house and were extremely lucky to get a mortgage at 9.98% interest due to a first time home buyers program in Ohio. I waited in line overnight outside the bank to get it. Regular rates were 14%.
We still live there, but have a condo in FL at 3%.
Given the relative tax rates, and the political climates, why don't you live in Florida and have a home in Ohio?
The Great Stagflation that MacAdoodle is talking about lasted over 10 years and required Volcker raising the prime Federal Funds rate to 20 percent before it was finally beaten back. We're not even two years into our current stagflation and real interest rates are still negative.
Our ass pain and suffering is just getting started, especially with this dickhead so-called "president".
I don't even think it's stagflation yet. I mean technically. As in, we're just at the beginning of what could be a very rough period, but the weird market corrections and fucked up supply chains and the pain from an impending housing market shock... it is hit and miss right now and the pessimism is really setting in.
Biden and his party with their constant attempt to fund more pork barrels, and to just straight give people money, don't inspire confidence. Like "Hey, look! A great big oil fire. I know, let's spray it with a hose!"
Let's smother it with kerosene, more like.
Stop ascribing to incompetence that which is obviously motivated by malice.
When bad things happen under a Democrat's watch, then it is a deliberate intent to destroy the country.
When bad things happen under a Republican's watch, then it's just one of those things that happens that is out of anyone's control, and it's still the Democrat's fault anyway.
You Obama-loving butt boys and kiddie fuckers despise America and the noble ideas underpinning the American Revolution and the 1789 Constitution. That's why you desperately want to "fundamentally transform" us into something more like communist China: a quasi-totalitarian, fully bureaucratized one party state with only the trappings of real representation.
99% of the time you shitbags deny this like you are now, but every rare once in a while one of you will fuck up and admit it, usually because you're drunk or high or you think no normal Americans are paying attention.
You're aren't fooling anyone, asswipe.
Funny how you switched parties thinking it would hide your projecting.
I didn't think it possible, but this is even more embarrassing than your usual idiocy.
This is true. It's all tribalism all the way down. Spending skyrocketed under Reagan, yet Clinton managed to balance the budget. It's like Bizarro World.
Spending skyrocketed under Reagan, yet Clinton managed to balance the budget.
Could that be because it's Congress that controls the budget and not the president?
Reagan had dems, Clinton had reps. For the first time in half a century, the GOP controlled congress. AAAAaaaand the budget got balanced.
What happened when Democrats got full control of the congress again?
I think it was called 'The Great Recession'......
It’s like Bizarro World.
Right-o!
Here let me summarize the article for the benefit of the commenters who didn't read it.
Carter was an idiot and/or deliberately malicious and so inflation spiraled out of control under his watch. Then when Reagan took over, because he was a Real Patriot and loved America, he single-handedly turned everything around and saved the nation.
Now, in the modern day, Trump the True Patriot tried to keep inflation under control but was continually thwarted by the Deep State that is full of America-Hating Marxist Assholes. So inflationary stimulus like the CARES Act was totally not his fault. How could it be? He is a patriot who loves America! So when he lost the election (which was totally rigged and stolen from him), and Biden took over, because he's a fellow Marxist who also hates America, he gave his marching orders to his lieutenants in the Deep State to ramp up the inflation to hasten the destruction of the country.
Therefore:
Democrats = evil traitors
Republicans = noble patriots
So vote Team Red in November!
Personally I approve when the leftists prove their insane bias so obviously. Good job!
I detected some bias in the comment as well.
Expect him to keep spiraling as things continue to go badly for his team.
I always thought it was sarc seeking your attaboys. Apparently you’re seeking his as you begin to act like him.
What a biased comment!
At least Sarcasmic manages to keep this type of commenting short and fairly succinct. Work better and apply yourself, Chemjeff.
Then the Gods of the Market tumbled, and their smooth-tongued wizards withdrew
And the hearts of the meanest were humbled and began to believe it was true
That All is not Gold that Glitters, and Two and Two make Four
And the Gods of the Copybook Headings limped up to explain it once more.
After this is accomplished, and the brave new world begins
When all men are paid for existing and no man must pay for his sins,
As surely as Water will wet us, as surely as Fire will burn,
The Gods of the Copybook Headings with terror and slaughter return!
Not only did [Nixon] fail to learn the lesson that price controls don't work, he made the same mistake twice.
Those were primitive times. Now we have the *technology* to make price controls work!
It's different this time.
Is America of 2022 simply repeating the mistakes of the 1960s and 1970s? It isn't a note-for-note remake, but it does feel rather like a remix, a collage of historically familiar elements rearranged and repackaged in an updated aesthetic.
Funny. This seems like it could be applied to a host of issues beyond inflation, from crime to urban renewal to social mores. We learned from bitter experience that progressivism simply doesn't work. But, you have a new generation mouthing off for whom the 1970s are as ancient history as the Great Depression was for people born in the 1970s. And they've had delusions that they're so much smarter than the generations before them pumped into their heads for the better part of twenty years. Well, maybe their children will recognize that maybe Chesterton's fence was put there for a reason.
Gosh, it's like kids today are a stupid as we were when we were their age!
There's a difference. I was at least looking for novel stupidities to try out.
We all were looking for novel stupidities. And what did we get? Stupid haircuts and music that offended our parents. And video games instead of pinball.
Smooth.
When an article mentions 70's inflation and fails to mention Paul Volcker, then we still aren't remotely serious about dealing with inflation.
Or Nixon cutting the dollar's last ties to gold in 1971.
I in no way want to defend Keynes, but much of the economic policies that people attribute to him were not his. He did say government should spend when times were bad, but he also say governments should cut back when times were good. No politician ever followed the latter advice. Keynes was just an excuse to spend more no matter what. They didn't care about his economics they just wanted an excuse to spend, spend, spend.
Yup.
His mantra was "timely, temporary, and targeted" and his particular band of stupidity was believing in government and politicians, just another self-deluded statist.
* Government burrocracies are too bloated to ever act timely.
* Government burrocrats' targets are chosen corruptly, not wisely.
* Only damned fools think government burrocrats and politicians know the meaning of temporary.
I'd add that timely and temporary assume some sort of omniscience on the part of even some hypothetically morally pure policy maker. Policy makers aren't supposed to cut "when times are good" and spend "when times are bad" under Keynesian theory. They're supposed to do those things when times are going to be good or bad. And they're supposed to do those things just enough in the future so that the money flows through the system at the right time to offset the changes in the economy.
Not only was he wrong in thinking that government can spend us into prosperity, but he was extremely stupid, as well, thinking politicians would reign in spending at any time.
>>Reagan may not have been correct about every specific claim he made in that exchange
you go and write a semi-accurate piece but then have to throw in the fuck you moment too lol
In August 1971, Nixon delivered a prime-time speech in which he announced that he was officially "ordering a freeze on all prices and wages throughout the United States for a period of 90 days"
Hold on. You can't say this. Inflation was all Carter's fault according to wingnut.com. Any mention of the inflation during the Nixon and Ford years must be expunged.
Somehow, you've managed to skip all mention of Johnson.
After leaving my previous job 12 months ago, i’ve had some good luck to learn about this website which was a life-saver for me.They offer jobs for which people can work online from their house. My latest paycheck after working for them for 4 months was for $4500.Amazing thing about is that the only thing required is simple typing skills and access to internet.
Read all about it here……..>>> OnlineCareer1
For Ford, it was the voters themselves.
"The voters" keep reelecting the same fraudsters and economically illiterate fucktards who promise them they can get something for nothing. "The voters" have repeatedly rejected anyone who said it was time to stop kicking the can down the road. Ford wasn't wrong.
I like Ford. Historically, and as a person (relative to politicians, though).
He was in an impossible spot. But, you're right. It's hard to be the guy telling everyone to eat their vegetables when they see ice cream in the next bowl.
He pardoned Nixon, that was his great sin in the eyes of so many voters.
Ford veto’d over twice as much legislation in his less-than-two-and-a-half years as president than George W. Bush and Barack Obama could be troubled to veto in 16 years. He did the country a favor by pardoning Nixon. He did the country a disfavor by ushering in Jimmy Carter.
Gee poor energy policy and endless money printing causes inflation. Who would have ever thought that? (sarc)
Reagan solved it by inducing a controlled recession, which caused some bitching at the time (you can see this in the original WKRP) but worked
Bailey.
"...a substantial reduction in typical family income, even as two-earner households became more common with the mass entry of women into the workforce."
Fox Butterfield, Is That You™?
Have lived through all the times written about. The big mistake Johnson made was not raising taxes in 1964, an election year, to pay for all the spending, both government and the war. For me that was the seed that began the inflation tragedy.
When the government is giving loan forgiveness to people making up to $125,000, when the median family of four income is $60,000 approximately, we are burning money to light cigarettes. Spending needs to be controlled and used for those in need, not for more votes from your base and those that will support you.
Until government tends to what it is supposedly limited to, this tragedy will continue repeatedly, like insanity, doing the same thing and expecting a different answer or result.
Of course, if Johnson had raised taxes to support The War On Poverty and The Vietnam War, people would have rebelled against them sooner.
"Until government tends to what it is supposedly limited to"
This doesn't include spending being "used for those in need".
What can the last two centuries teach us about U.S. politics?
The American experiment, i.e., sovereign citizens, not sovereign govt., is not realized with the present political paradigm, namely, a coercive govt., a govt. based on the initiation of force, threats, instead of reason, rights, choice. Voting isn't choice. It's the opposite. Voting is asking someone else to choose for you, and then force that choice on all, even the citizens who want to self-govern, to live & let live. That is not unique to the USA. It's the same in every country. Failure, tyranny varies, by degree, not in principle.
The D.O.I. advocates rebellion, rejection of the political system that fails its citizens. Good advice. How about we choose the opposite basis for governing? Non-violence against innocent citizens who only dissent, only want to be left alone to exercise their rights and pursue their happiness with others who choose the same. For example, rules don't require rulers. Remember, rulers enforce, but they don't follow rules. You want to continue to live under their boot?
Where's Suderman getting this from? " And from December 1971 to December 1972, the country's money supply grew precipitously, from $228 billion to $249 billion."
Secondly, weird how the growth in M2 was well below 10% from 78-82 yet inflation was at its highest point during those years. Weird.
Weird how m2 grew at over 10% from 71-73 yet inflation was lower those years.
Also weird that from 75-78 growth in M2 was again above 10% but inflation was dropping,,,rapdily during those years.
Almost makes one come to realize that Friedman was wrong.
Inflation is always and everywhere an ENERGY phenomenon.
Time to change perspectives libertarians.
Now, in the modern day, Trump the True Patriot tried to keep inflation under control but was continually thwarted by the Deep State that is full of America-Hating Marxist Assholes, Thanks for the article.
please visit -->... Masandi Wibowo
No they did not vote for Reagan for a multitude of reasons, we voted for him because the Jimmy Carter economy was terrible and the regular working folks were in trouble. The left has complained about Reagan ever since even though his time in office was a time that we had a good life economically. Sure he raised the deficit but he also stimulated the economy and had more taxpayer money flowing into the coffers, what he did worked. Only president that when he changed the tax brackets I could actually see I got more of my own money. I liked Clinton too, he knew to leave success alone when the dotcom revolution arrived. Politics and social media now work to divide us and we are all supposed to hate each other. Just think that Reagan won 49 states on his second term. I don't think that could ever happen now.
Keynes never advocated the economic malpractice that is being committed in his name these days.