The Volokh Conspiracy
Mostly law professors | Sometimes contrarian | Often libertarian | Always independent
Defending the Court of International Trade Ruling Against Trump's Tariffs - A Reply to John Yoo
Yoo's criticisms are off the mark, for a variety of reasons. But, tellingly, he actually agrees Trump's IEEPA tariffs are illegal, merely disagreeing with the court's reasons for reaching that conclusion.

In a previous post, I responded to Prof. Jack Goldsmith's critique of the recent US Court of International Trade decision striking down Donald Trump's massive "Liberation Day" tariffs in a case brought by the Liberty Justice Center and myself. In this one, I respond to a critique by UC Berkelely law Prof. John Yoo. Like Goldsmith's arguments, Yoo's fall short - and for some of the same reasons.
Like Goldsmith, Yoo doesn't actually conclude that the CIT got the result wrong, but instead has various reservations about its reasoning. Indeed, he seems to agree that the court reached the right result, merely disagreeing with the way it got there.
Yoo acknowledges that "the trade deficit does not amount to an actual national emergency and that tariffs make no economic sense." If there is no actual national emergency, then the president cannot use the International Emergency Economic Powers Act ("IEEPA") at all, much less start what Yoo describes as an "unprecedented trade war." IEEPA states that the law can only be invoked if the president declares a "national emergency" with respect to an "unusual and extraordinary threat, which has its source in whole or substantial part outside the United States, to the national security, foreign policy, or economy of the United States." No emergency, no tariffs!
Yoo also recognizes that the CIT "could have agreed to reject the tariffs on the straightforward ground that the trade deficit does not qualify as 'an unusual and extraordinary threat' to the national security, foreign policy, or economy of the United States, as required by IEEPA." I agree again! And, as I noted in my response to Goldsmith, the CIT in fact did emphasize that these IEEPA requirements "impose meaningful limits on any such authority it confers," and therefore rejected the Administration's claim that the statute authorizes unlimited presidential discretion to impose tariffs. Only such unlimited discretionary power could possibly justify the "Liberation Day" tariffs, as Yoo himself recognizes when he concedes that trade deficits aren't actually an emergency or an "an unusual and extraordinary threat."
It is extremely telling that Yoo believes Trump was wrong to declare an emergency here and to label trade deficits "an unusual and extraordinary threat." And he apparently rejects the administration's argument that these are "political questions" exempt from judicial review. If academia's leading advocate of sweeping executive power over foreign affairs thinks an invocation of emergency powers goes too far, that's a strong sign it's illegal!
Yoo complains that the CIT wrongly relied on the "major questions doctrine," which which requires Congress to "speak clearly" when authorizing the executive to make "decisions of vast economic and political significance." He argues that "[m]ajor questions orders courts to stop the executive branch from seizing broad economic, political, or social powers by reading vague statutes too broadly," yet "IEEPA is no vague statute" because it "directly addresses international emergencies…. and intentionally vested the President with broad economic powers to meet them." But the key question here is whether IEEPA clearly gives the persistent virtually unlimited discretion to impose tariffs. Since the statute doesn't actually mention tariffs at all, and it can only be invoked at all if there is an emergency and an "unusual and extraordinary threat," there is no such clear grant of unlimited tariff authority. And there is also no doubt that the power to start a massive trade war raises a "major question." For those reasons, MQD clearly does apply, and leads to the conclusion that the administration's tariffs are illegal.
Yoo argues that courts have previously held that IEEPA's grant of power to "regulate . . . importation . . . of . . . any property in which any foreign country or a national thereof has any interest" includes various authorities that are not specifically mentioned. But, as discussed in my response to Goldsmith, "regulation" and imposition of tariffs are historically distinct powers. At the very least, it is not unequivocally clear that the grant of the former authority necessarily includes unlimited power to use the latter. Under MQD, that means the administration should lose.
Yoo also argues that MQD and the nondelegation doctrine - which limits congressional delegation of legislative power to the president - do not apply to "foreign affairs." He cites United States v. Curtiss-Wright Export Corp. (1936) to support that position. But Curtiss-Wright did not endorse unlimited foreign-affairs delegation. It merely ruled greater discretion must often be granted to the President in the foreign affairs realm, but not unlimited discretion. It reasoned that legislation "within the international field must often accord to the President a degree of discretion and freedom from statutory restriction which would not be admissible were domestic affairs alone involved" A greater degree of discretion need not be unlimited. Moreover, the Supreme Court has specifically repudiated the notion that Curtiss-Wright grants the President unlimited authority over foreign affairs. In Zivotofsky v. Kerry (2015), the Court emphasized that "Curtiss-Wright did not hold that the President is free from Congress' lawmaking power in the field of international relations" and that "[t]he Executive is not free from the ordinary controls and checks of Congress merely because foreign affairs are at issue."
This is particularly true when, as the CIT noted, we are dealing with a power that the Constitution explicitly assigns to Congress. The CIT ruling rightly emphasizes that "The Constitution assigns Congress the exclusive powers to 'lay and collect Taxes, Duties, Imposts and Excises,' and to 'regulate Commerce with foreign Nations.'" There is no reason to apply MQD and nondelegation to the tariff power any differently from any other congressional authority.
Yoo claims a distinction is warranted because sudden crises arise in foreign policy "while In domestic affairs, problems usually do not suddenly arise that inflict great harm on the nation." But sudden crises happen in domestic affairs, as well, as witness such events as the Great Depression, the Civil War, and the Covid pandemic. If a special exception to nondelegation is warranted with respect to foreign policy, it should at least be limited to genuine emergencies. And Yoo himself acknowledges that trade deficits don't qualify as such.
Like Goldsmith, Yoo complains that the CIT was wrong to reject the fentanyl tariffs against Canada, Mexico, and China on the grounds they don't "deal" with the supposed "threat" at issue. But, like Goldsmith, he overlooks the fact that the administration's rationale for those tariffs requires virtually unlimited tariff authority.
Yoo worries that the CIT's reasoning would prevent the use of IEEPA to impose "economic sanctions aimed at specific countries, based on specific findings of their threat to U.S. national security and foreign policy." But, at least in many cases, such sanctions do directly "deal" with a "threat" in a way the fentanyl tariffs do not. While the latter ostensibly aim to create "leverage" to force the foreign power to address a drug-smuggling trade it is not responsible for, the former punish that government's own wrongdoing and diminish its resources so as to reduce its ability to continue to pose a threat. And, as noted in my response to Goldsmith, the amount of fentanyl entering the US from Canada is negligible, and most of that from Mexico is brought in by US citizens (whom the Mexican government cannot and should not prevent from returning home). If that is enough of a linkage to an "unusual and extraordinary threat" to justify imposition of massive tariffs under IEEPA, then anything is.
Like Yoo, I will be happy if appellate courts uphold the CIT ruling on the ground that there is no genuine national emergency here or because there is no "unusual and extraordinary threat." But they would also be justified in striking down Trump's IEEPA tariffs under MQD or nondelegation, or - like the recent US District Court of DC (DDC) ruling against the tariffs - because IEEPA doesn't authorize the use of tariffs at all.
As the CIT and DDC both recognized, the tariffs can also be invalidated under the rule of constitutional avoidance, which requires courts to avoid interpreting federal statutes in ways that raise constitutional problems, so long as there is a "fairly possible" alternative. Here it is obviously "fairly possible" for courts to avoid the nondelegation issue by concluding that IEEPA doesn't authorize tariffs, that there is no national emergency, that there is no "unusual and extraordinary threat," or that the administration should lose under the major questions doctrine. Indeed, Yoo himself agrees with two of these arguments.
Editor's Note: We invite comments and request that they be civil and on-topic. We do not moderate or assume any responsibility for comments, which are owned by the readers who post them. Comments do not represent the views of Reason.com or Reason Foundation. We reserve the right to delete any comment for any reason at any time. Comments may only be edited within 5 minutes of posting. Report abuses.
Please
to post comments
I count five or six solid reasons for the court to reject the tariffs (depending on how you count). One doesn't have to accept them all, seems like any one of them is a solid reason to invalidate the tariffs.
Meanwhile,the administration's argument that these are "political questions" exempt from judicial review is so overly broad and would lead to absurd consequences if applied consistently that it's not really much of an argument at all. And it appears that that is all they've got.
Potentially every tax challenge could be a political question not subject to judicial review.
I think tarriffs are a hybrid, sui generis animal. As foreign policy tools, Congress has more leeway to delegate decision-making authority to the President than it does for purely domestic matters. But as taxes, Congress must specify its delegation of authority clearly and specifically.
I completely agree that taxing and regulation are separate things. The Constitution permits Congress to regulate interstate commerce; it permits it to impose taxes for the general welfare of the United States.
Because the Framers made the regulatory and the taxing powers completely separate Congressional powers in the Constitution, I think this forces a conclusion that the delegation of one power to the President does not imply the delegation of the other. Rather, Congress must specify each power it is delegating separately, and also provide meaningful criteria for when and the extent to which the delegated power can be used.
Potentially every tax challenge could be a political question not subject to judicial review.
Potentially every [fill in the blank] challenge could be a political question not subject to judicial review, at least according to the administration's attorneys. And without articulating some limitations of this broad assertion of judicial impotence it's unlikely to be taken seriously by the courts.
There are several reasons why the tariff proclamation doesn’t pass legal muster. I’m not sure why preferring one reason over another is such a big deal.
At first glance, it appears that Yoo is prefering statutory interpretation grounds to constitutional grounds. I agree with this. It’s a standard canon of federal judicial decision making. And Yoo is right that the constitutional questions potentially implicate a large number of other matters well beyond what’s before the court and courts should exercise restraint and not decide more than what’s necessary. So while I disagree with his statement that there’s no difference between tariffs and domestic taxes for non-delegation doctrine purposes, I completely agree that there is absolutely no need to decide this question in this case.
I would also note that Professor Somin conflates an “emergency” with “unusual and extraordinary circumstances.” The Court of International Trade said that the two concepts are legally distinct. The Court accepted for purposes of its decision the Administration’s argument that so far as the IEEPA is concerned, an “emergency” exists whenever the President signs a document saying so. The court expressly declined to review whether an “emergency” exists or not. It left the question of reviewability of the President’s proclamation undecided. Rather, the Court’s position was that in addition to a potentially unreviewable Presidentially-proclaimed emergency, the IEEPA requires that there must also be “unusual and extraordinary circumstances.” And THAT, the Court of International Trade held, the judiciary gets to review.
It may be a distinction without a difference in this case. But it has potential implications for other cases involving other laws where the existence of a presidentially declared emergency is relevant to their applicability.
There are several reasons why the tariff proclamation doesn’t pass legal muster. I’m not sure why preferring one reason over another is such a big deal.
It depends on what you’re trying to do. If you have the real world objective of getting Trump’s tariffs cancelled, then it doesn’t matter which legal argument finds favor with the judges.
But if you’re interested from a law prof point of view – ie whether any particular arguments are rational, logical, coherent etc in themselves – then you need to look at the quality of the particular argument for each objection.
And Somin’s argument :
Since the statute doesn’t actually mention tariffs at all
qualifies as Warp Factor 9 bananas. Because :
1. the statute uses the general word “regulation” and doesn’t mention any particular specific form of regulation
2. so Somin’s argument would nix all specific forms of regulation as well as tariffs – including bans, quotas, component content, quality, health, safety controls, inspection regimes, labelling, mode of transport, timing of import, storage and security until cleared, and so on all the way to form filling at any and all stages.
3. tariffs are clearly more “major” in their impact on the liberties of importers and their customers than other forms of regulation such as form filling and inspection. But they are clearly less “major” than things like bans and quotas, and some variants of health, safety, quality regulation. Tariffs are not an elephant hidden in a mousehole, they are the normal size of crittur for a “regulation”-hole.
So there may be many good legal reasons for nixing the tariffs. But that “tariff`’ is not explicity mentioned, or that a tariff power involves a “major question” while a ban or quota power doesn’t. are not among them.
As to Warp Factor 9 bananas, the Constitution puts regulation and taxation in completely different clauses. Congress has broad power to tax for the general welfare of the United States. But it can only has a much more limited power to regulate. It can only regulate specific enumerated things - commerce between the several states, navigable waters, stuff like that.
If it’s Warp Factor 9 bananas to treat the two as different powers, how do you explain how the Framers dealt with them in the written Constititution? Were the Framers all Warp Factor 9 bananas?
If in her Will, Mrs Moore bequeaths to me :
(1) all of her jewelry, and
(2) all chattels that I previously gave to her
your position would seem to be that the wedding ring I gave her does not fall within the meaning of “all chattels that I previously gave to her” because it already falls within the meaning of “all of her jewelry” *
This strikes me as somewhat eccentric.
A tariff is both a tax and a form of regulation of foreign commerce. That it falls within two of the enumerated powers does not affect that conclusion.
Um, that's untrue, and the actual text of the statute works against your argument. In addition to "regulate," IEEPA expressly authorizes the president to "prevent or prohibit" any "acquisition, holding… transportation, importation or exportation of, or dealing in…" foreign goods. If your interpretation were correct, those words would all be superfluous, because "regulate" would cover all of that.
Quiet in here. Is the bot server off-line today?
Isn't Yoo the man who justified torture at Gitmo? Surely he could put up a better justification of tariffs if he put his mind to it.
I was just thinking the same thing …water boarding is kosher but tariffs are not. Btw, I actually agree with Yoo on torture and Democrats and the media really screwed up the issue. The issue should have always been about eliciting false confessions which is wrong irrespective of whether or not torture is used. So I support torturing high value detainees with doctors standing nearby but I oppose getting puppies to tickle a detainee’s feet to elicit a false confession. Bush/Cheney were pressuring CIA interrogators to elicit false confessions tying 9/11 to Saddam in 2002 to lie us into a war.
While LA was burning, Ilya Somin posted in support of the rioters. He wrote: "civilians ... have a right to resist in ways that would otherwise be illegal and unjustified." He does disapprove of “violence that harms innocent people”, but the post implies that everything else is okay with him.
At least the Reichstag fire was an actual fire.
Your analysis is flawed. There isn’t any behavior that could be described as rioting that would not have the potential to hurt innocent people. Whereas what he wrote can be reasonably interpreted as approving of activities such as trespassing, failure to disperse or obey police orders, etc.
Yes, that suggests that innocent people will be hurt by what Somin advocates.