The Volokh Conspiracy
Mostly law professors | Sometimes contrarian | Often libertarian | Always independent
Defending the Court of International Trade Ruling Against Trump's Tariffs—A Reply to Jack Goldsmith
The CIT ruling is much stronger than Prof. Goldsmith contends. The same is true of a related ruling by federal District Court Judge Rudolph Contreras.

Many prominent legal scholars and former government officials across the political spectrum have supported the lawsuit challenging Trump's "Liberation Day" tariffs brought by the Liberty Justice Center and myself, and backed the recent US Court of International Trade decision in our favor. But the ruling does have its critics, and one of the most prominent is Harvard law Prof. Jack Goldsmith. He doesn't actually conclude the ruling is wrong. But he clearly has serious reservations about it, outlined in a notable article on the Executive Functions substack, where he also criticizes the recent US District Court of DC (DDC) ruling against the tariffs. In this post, I explain why those reservations are generally misplaced.
As the CIT opinion emphasized, the key factor behind the decision was the "unbounded" nature of the tariff authority claimed by Trump: "The question in the two cases before the court is whether the International Emergency Economic Powers Act of 1977 ("IEEPA") delegates…. to the President…. authority to impose unlimited tariffs on goods from nearly every country in the world." The CIT ruled IEEPA did not grant such limitless power, and that it would be an unconstitutional delegation of legislative power if it did.
Goldsmith contends "the administration did not claim an unbounded or limitless power" because "Trump's tariffs complied with IEEPA's substantive and procedural requirements." He notes that Trump declared a "national emergency" with respect to trade deficits and further claimed the deficits are an "unusual and extraordinary threat" to the US economy and national security, thus supposedly meeting IEEPA's requirements.
But Goldsmith overlooks the fact that the administration consistently maintained that the president has absolute, unreviewable discretion to determine qualifies as a "national emergency" and an "unusual and extraordinary threat." And if trade deficits—which are completely normal and not a threat at all—qualify as an "unusual and extraordinary threat," so can virtually anything. This is undeniably a claim to unlimited tariff authority. And the CIT rightly concluded as much.
As CIT Judge Jane Restani put it in oral argument, the administration's position would allow the president to impose tariffs for any "crazy" reason, such as a "peanut butter shortage." Indeed, the hypothetical peanut shortage tariff would be less abusive and ridiculous than Trump's trade-deficit rationale. Peanut butter shortages are at least somewhat unusual, and would be a genuine problem, whereas trade deficits are neither.
The CIT also rightly concluded that IEEPA doesn't leave determination of what tariffs to impose entirely up to the president: "IEEPA's provisions… impose meaningful limits on any such authority it confers." Such boundless discretion would render the words "unusual and extraordinary threat" superfluous (thereby violating a basic rule of statutory interpretation), and also create an unconstitutional delegation of "unbounded tariff authority to the President."
Goldsmith also criticizes the CIT and DDC's reliance on the "major questions" doctrine, which requires Congress to "speak clearly" when authorizing the executive to make "decisions of vast economic and political significance." Trump's gargantuan IEEPA tariffs—starting the biggest trade war since the Great Depression and imposing some 1.4 to 2.2 trillion dollars in new taxes on Americans—raise a major question, if anything does. And the fact that no previous president has used IEEPA to impose any tariffs at all satisfy the additional criterion that MQD scrutiny is stronger when an assertion of power is unprecedented.
Goldsmith notes that a 1975 United States Court of Customs and Patent Appeals (CCPA) ruling in the Yoshida case upheld the Richard Nixon's imposition of tariffs under the Trading with the Enemy Act (TWEA), the predecessor statute to Yoshida. But, as the CIT ruling explains at length, Yoshida did not rule that TWEA authorizes unlimited tariff authority, and indeed emphasized that such unlimited delegation would be unconstitutional. Moreover, in enacting IEEPA, Congress sought to limit previous presidential emergency powers, not perpetuate them. As a House of Representatives report leading to the enactment of IEEPA put it, the legislation is based on "a recognition that emergencies are by their nature rare and brief, and are not to be equated with normal ongoing problems." Using IEEPA emergency powers to address "normal ongoing problems" is precisely what Trump is trying to do here.
Goldsmith also raises (without endorsing) the possibility that MQD does not apply to policies adopted by the president, as opposed to subordinate executive branch officials. I responded to that argument in detail here.
While not addessed in our case, a similar lawsuit filed by 12 states led by Oregon and decided in the same CIT ruling, also challenged Trump's fentanyl-related IEEPA tariffs against Canada, Mexico, and China. The CIT ruled that those tariffs were not meaningfully "deal with" any "unusual and extraordinary threat" created by fentanyl smuggling. Trump argued the tariffs address the threat by creating "leverage" against the three countries, which was not a direct enough link, according to the court. Goldsmith contends that an indirect link is enough. But if creating potential leverage against some government —including one that isn't even causing the threat—is enough of a connection than we have a backdoor to unlimited power. Virtually any tariff can potentially be used as leverage against some government to try to get them to do something that might potentially help curb a threat.
The amount of fentanyl entering the US from Canada is negligible, and most of that from Mexico is brought in by US citizens (whom the Mexican government cannot and should not prevent from returning home). If that is enough of a linkage to an "unusual and extraordinary threat" to justify the imposition of massive tariffs under IEEPA, then anything is. Thus, CIT was right to reject Trump's fentanyl tariffs, as well as the Liberation Day ones.
Goldsmith also criticizes the DDC decision, which unlike the CIT (which did not address this issue), ruled that IEEPA doesn't authorize the imposition of tariffs at all. IEEPA nowhere even uses the word "tariff" or any synonym. Instead, it authorizes the president to "regulate . . . importation . . . of . . . any property in which any foreign country or a national thereof has any interest." DDC Judge Rudolph Contreras rightly concluded that regulation and taxation are distinct powers, and thus the former does not include the latter. If the power to "regulate" includes an unlimited power to impose tariffs, then the Constitution's grant to Congress of the power to "lay and collect Taxes, Duties, Imposts and Excises" would be superfluous, since Congress also has the authority to "regulate Commerce with foreign Nations." At the very least, the power to "regulate" cannot create an unlimited power to impose tariffs. Judge Contreras' opinion includes a detailed discussion of the distinction between the two powers that Goldsmith largely fails to address.
I do agree with Goldsmith that the major questions doctrine likely to be an important issue as these cases proceed on appeal. But appellate courts also have plenty of other reasons to affirm the CIT and DDC rulings against Trump's tariffs.
Editor's Note: We invite comments and request that they be civil and on-topic. We do not moderate or assume any responsibility for comments, which are owned by the readers who post them. Comments do not represent the views of Reason.com or Reason Foundation. We reserve the right to delete any comment for any reason at any time. Comments may only be edited within 5 minutes of posting. Report abuses.
Please
to post comments
Fentanyl deaths spiked in 2020 when illegal border crossings were at record lows!! Both fentanyl deaths and violent crime spiked in April 2020 and so it appears the proximate cause was the PPP and sibling programs…let’s hand our dollars with no oversight and see what happens!! Ooops, thugs bought guns and fentanyl and now we have a crime wave! The Trump administration should just argue it’s their incompetence that is the “emergency”…the court would have to agree with them on that! 😉
The fentanyl crisis may be a factor in the suppression of crime in official statistics of crime. Crime has updated, the lawyer profession has not. There is likely a billion or more crimes. Count drug use, the number may be 2 billion. There are 2 million prosecutions. Crime pays big time, thanks to the utter failure of the lawyer profession. The number of murders may not be 20000, since there are 100000 unresolved missing persons reports. The criminal law is in utter failure. The lawyer needs to be cancelled.
If the President has inherent powers to federalize the militia to enforce general federal laws, why did the Framers see fit to enumerate specific circumstances when the President had the power to call in the militia. For decoration?
If we roll the constitution up and smoke it, it seems we can always find penumbras and emanations ir structures in the resulting haze that can support any outcome we want.
The idea the President has inherent unienumerated powers to call forth troups is a recipe for dictatorship.
The president can only call forth troops to suppresss domestic violence at the request of a state’s government. He can only call forth troops to repel invasions or enforce 14th and 15th Anendment rights if authorized by Congress. He has no constitutional power to call forth troops on his own, without some other body – state governor or Congress – acting as a check.
This is absolutely the intent of the Framers. And this intent is critical, foundational, to our constitutional structure.
We do not have a Weimar constitution.
Volokh argues that the fact the president can call forth the militia undermines the notion that it was a check on tyranny. Volokh simply ignores the fact the states appoint officers and so the militia would have always been loyal to the state. Also, we had a civil war in which prominent federal Army officers were loyal to their respective states and so it’s pretty obvious the states would have been able to appoint militia officers loyal to the state.
The Framers placed limitations on the President’s power to call forth the militia for domestic matters, including requiring the authorization of another person or body before proceeding. This was absolutely intended as a check on tyrrany.
Volokh’s objective was obfuscating the word “militia” in the 2A because his goal was a RKBA that protected the right for individuals and not for the respective state militias.
Oh, and he didn’t want to involve the right to privacy which is what some on the Left believe protects the individual right to self-defense.
Where is the lawsuit claiming the President doesn’t have the authority to do this?
Surely there are enough lawyers around interested in the issue to file one.
Goldsmith…. notes that Trump declared a “national emergency” with respect to trade deficits and further claimed the deficits are an “unusual and extraordinary threat” to the US economy and national security, thus supposedly meeting IEEPA’s requirements.
Goldsmith can swallow this hook, line, and sinker, if he likes, but that doesn’t make it true, or require that Congress, the courts, and the citizenry accept Trump’s declaration as anything more than hogwash.
Judge Restani is of course correct that if you let this go you will let anything go. Among other things, that clearly defeats Goldsmith’s contention that “the administration did not claim an unbounded or limitless power,” since such a power is logically implied by unquestioning acceptance of Trump’s claims.
So does Somin advocate rioting over this Trump policy also?
Yes, Cubans in Miami rioted over Elian Gonzalez. And Republicans rioted the same year during the recount in West Palm Beach.
You are lying or you can’t read. Somin did not advocate rioting on the other comment regarding ICE. There he wrote “None of this suggests that protestors are entitled to do whatever they want. Rioting and other violence that harms innocent people is still both illegal and wrong.”
Referring to the rioters, Somin wrote: “civilians … have a right to resist in ways that would otherwise be illegal and unjustified.”
You are lying or you can’t read as Somin wrote the following:
“When law enforcement agencies themselves engage in systematic lawlessness, they are not entitled to the deference and cooperation they might otherwise expect from civilians. The latter have a right to resist in ways that would otherwise be illegal and unjustified. This point is distinct from traditional rationales for civil disobedience that may apply even in situations where government officials are acting completely legally, but the underlying laws are themselves severely unjust (as is also often true in the immigration field). There is additional justification for civilian resistance to and noncooperation with law enforcement, when it is the latter who are acting unlawfully.
None of this suggests that protestors are entitled to do whatever they want. Rioting and other violence that harms innocent people is still both illegal and wrong. What I wrote in 2020 at the time of the George Floyd protests—many of which degenerated into riots and looting—remains applicable today:
Much can be done to roll back abusive law enforcement practices…. But one tactic that must be avoided is the kind of rioting and looting that has occurred over the last few days…
Most of the damage caused by rioting is inflicted on innocent people who are in no way responsible for police abuses. Destruction and looting of stores and other businesses not only hurts the owners and employees of those enterprises, but also impoverishes the broader communities of which they are a part. Violence and violation of property rights reduce investment and economic development, which predictably exacerbates the poverty of minority inner-city neighborhoods. The negative economic effects can persist for many years.
It may be tempting to say that rioting and other similar violence is justified if you are doing it in the name of a just cause. But even people with legitimate grievances must still observe moral limits on tactics they use to pursue them. Ignoring this principle is a recipe for disaster.”
I guess you are agreeing that I quoted Somin accurately.
Have you decided on if he’s a Marxist or a fascist yet?
I think Somin is more of a Gramsci Marxist.
One thing Gramsci Marxists loved was limiting the powers of the state!
Stop beclowning yourself.
I repeat: Is there any way an action can be brought against Prof. Somin for illegal monopolization of a blog?
The last four posts on this blog (other than a tiny scheduled daily factoid about the Supreme Court) have been posted by Prof. Somin. But worse, each of them is so long that they stretch the definition of “blog” as opposed to online magazine. They’re each article length. And worse yet, each of his posts is always like this historically and has been for years; and he never uses the click-for-more option, shoving his repetitive, rehearsed positions in the reader’s face and forcing us to manually scroll past every word. I’m starting to kind of dread checking this blog. Don’t we have better things to do than have avalanches of mediocre arguments pushed into our face by one poster who’s so incredibly boring that, like Bilbo Baggins at the beginning of The Hobbit, you know in advance what his opinion will be on any subject he might talk about without the bother of asking him?
A while back, I asked whether there is there any way that an action can be brought against Prof. Somin for illegally monopolizing this formerly ‘group’ blog. I raise the question again. The need to stop Ilya’s ill-argued Ilyaruptions is now even more urgent. This is getting ridiculous.
The last four posts on this blog (other than a tiny scheduled daily factoid about the Supreme Court) have been posted by Prof. Somin. Worse, each of them is so long that they stretch the definition of “blog” as opposed to online magazine. They’re each article length. I have no interest in visiting an online magazine where I am forced to ‘read’ every word written by Prof. Somin.
And worse yet, each of his posts is always like this historically, and has been for years; and he never uses the click-for-more option — this shoving his repetitive, rehearsed positions in the reader’s face and forcing each of us to manually scroll past every word.
I’m starting to kind of dread checking this blog. Don’t we have better things to do than have avalanches of mediocre arguments pushed into our face almost every day by one single poster who’s so predictable and low-interest that, like Bilbo Baggins at the beginning of The Hobbit, you know in advance what his opinion will be on any subject he might talk about without the bother of asking him first?
At one time, Bernstein was the most disliked poster. Now it is Somin by a wide margin. It is the same predictable garbage all the time, and he does not even have the intellectual honesty to respond to comments.
It’s Berenstain.
Trumps tariffs apply to virtually all countries of the world. What IEEPA economic emergency do the following small countries: Gambia, Togo, Sao Tome & Principe, Lesotho (Africa), Trinidad and Tobago, Fiji, East Timor, etc pose to the United States?
No president in the world has ever asserted so much power over international trade.
The Republican Congress has abdicated its constitutional responsibility to impose tariffs on America’s main adversary–China.