A Rare Win for Sanity in U.S. Tariff Policy
The U.S. International Trade Commission voted unanimously to reject a nakedly protectionist proposal that would have made canned goods more expensive.

From the start, the proposal to enact new tariffs on the metal used primarily to make tin cans was naked protectionism that would have benefitted one company while being costly for consumers and many American businesses.
This time, however, sanity prevailed.
The International Trade Commission (ITC) voted unanimously this week to reject those proposed tariffs, which would have been charged on tin-plate steel imported from Canada, China, Germany, and South Korea. The ruling should put an end to a monthslong battle between Cleveland-Cliffs, the metal manufacturer that sought the tariffs, and various groups representing the downstream industries and consumers that would have borne the tariffs' cost.
Imports from abroad "do not injure U.S. industry," the ITC concluded, ruling against Cleveland-Cliffs' allegations of dumping—that is, the deliberate pricing of exports in order to undercut industry in another country.
"Today's result confirms what we've known all along—there was no merit to Cleveland-Cliffs' claims," David Chavern, president and CEO of the Consumer Brands Association, a trade group representing many of the food and home goods suppliers that stood to be harmed by the tariffs, said in a statement. "The ITC not only voted today to protect thousands of American manufacturing jobs, but to preserve the integrity of our country's trade remedy process."
That process is a windy, bureaucratic one that is often deliberately stacked against the interests of consumers—as I explored in an episode of Reason's Why We Can't Have Nice Things podcast series last year. In the case of the tin-plate steel tariffs, as with many instances of protectionism, the costs would have been diffused across the economy while the benefits would have accumulated for Cleveland-Cliffs, which hoped to raise barriers to imported metal as a way to protect its own bottom line.
In the original proposal, Cleveland-Cliffs sought tariffs of up to 300 percent. At that level, the Consumer Brands Association estimated that the tariffs could raise the price of a single can of soup by 58 cents—a reflection of the fact that the can itself is often the most expensive part of any canned food—at a time when consumers are already battling high inflation. Separately, a study by Trade Partnership Worldwide LLC, a pro-trade think tank, found that 600 jobs would be put at risk for every tin-plate steel-making job protected by the proposed tariffs.
Importing tin-plate steel is essential for American-based can manufacturers because the domestic supply of the metal (from Cleveland-Cliffs and other smaller suppliers) is inadequate to meet demand. In 2022, Cleveland-Cliffs supplied just 64 percent of the volume needed by can makers and delivered only 15 percent of that volume on time, according to a report by The Can Institute, an industry group that opposed the tariff request and cheered the ITC's ruling.
In January, the Commerce Department narrowed the scope of the tariff request before passing the matter over to the ITC for a final determination. It excluded imports from four other countries—the Netherlands, Taiwan, Turkey, and the United Kingdom—from Cleveland-Cliffs' original petition and recommended lower tariff levels than had originally been sought.
In rejecting that more limited tariff proposal, then, the ITC has sent a clear message about how outlandish the original effort was. Cleveland-Cliffs' request for federal protectionism was obviously a terrible idea, and its rejection is a nice reminder that American industry isn't helped by raising barriers to foreign goods.
Editor's Note: As of February 29, 2024, commenting privileges on reason.com posts are limited to Reason Plus subscribers. Past commenters are grandfathered in for a temporary period. Subscribe here to preserve your ability to comment. Your Reason Plus subscription also gives you an ad-free version of reason.com, along with full access to the digital edition and archives of Reason magazine. We request that comments be civil and on-topic. We do not moderate or assume any responsibility for comments, which are owned by the readers who post them. Comments do not represent the views of reason.com or Reason Foundation. We reserve the right to delete any comment and ban commenters for any reason at any time. Comments may only be edited within 5 minutes of posting. Report abuses.
Please
to post comments
Not a win at at all. An unelected governmemental body has no more authority to set tax rates as the president. Only Congress does.
NO TAXATION WITHOUT REPRESENTATION!
In this case, no taxes were imposed, so yes, a win.
NO TAXATION WITHOUT REPRESENTATION!
That principle was never part of US constitutional jurisprudence. And ask any conservative whether green card holders should be allowed to vote because they pay US taxes...
People are happier if they are more financially independent. Make 120 to 180USD / Hr by performing as4 simple tasks. We can help you achieve this. Join our strong community and earn money easily and safely from wherever you want.
Take a look............................................ http://Www.Bizwork1.com
Tax-Exception for special trade channels without Representation for the WIN! /s
So long as the 'purse' resides in the House of Representatives you are F.O.S. and no; non-citizens do not get to vote on the citizens nation of laws just because they are visiting.
The ITC is quasi-judicial which is an ok function. But clearly its board is part of the DC clusterfuck. Six members - two of which are vacant, three of which terms have expired, and the remaining member term expires end of this year.
"But clearly its board is part of the DC clusterfuck. Six members"
Are these members elected by the public? My guess is that they aren't and the public has no say at all in their operations. It seems like it's policy for and by technocrats.
The case in this article is about an allegation of dumping and predatory pricing. You can argue that none of those sorts of allegations or claims should ever have standing in any court. In this case it is an administrative law court. But you are then also saying that it's not a peaceably actionable harm and that there are a slew of harms whose remedy is outside the law.
Regardless of how far you want to argue down that path, there's no value whatsoever in positing that an elected official is the exact skill set needed to adjudicate this sort of issue.
Just to be clear, this was NOT a rejection of protective tariffs in general. The Trade Commission and the Commerce Department still exist to pick winners and losers, and Americans will continue to be the losers in the long run.
"dumping—that is, the deliberate pricing of exports in order to undercut industry in another country."
More specifically, pricing exports BELOW COST to undercut industry in another country to drive them out of business (theoretically with the expectation that one can later raise prices). The likelihood that producers in four countries as disparate as Canada, China, Germany, and South Korea would all be willing and able to dump simultaneously is pretty remote.
"Imports from abroad "do not injure U.S. industry,""
If those Imports are Tax & Regulation Free, created by less than "minimum-wage", have subsidized rates of shipping or are insured any international justice (National Defense) they sure as heck do.
There's a reason the US used Tariffs to fund National Defense at its origin. Because that's the international trade market.
That day the "free trade" bandwagon went from universal "free trade" to only foreign nations get "free trade".
Someone manipulated/polluted the bandwagons agenda.
Is there a Libertarian case for free trade and comparative advantage? I remember reading that the case was originally made by Ricardo in the early 19th century. He examined two countries, Britain and Portugal, and two commodities, cloth and wine, and showed that comparative advantage was a thing. But in reality, the global economy consists of dozens of countries trading 1000s of commodities, and it's impossible to show that comparative advantage exists. The mathematics is just too complicated so it's ultimately a matter of faith, not science, or even social science.
"...and it’s impossible to show that comparative advantage exists..."
You,
Are,
Full.
Of.
Shit,
Nazi scum. Fuck off and die:
mtrueman|8.30.17 @ 1:42PM|#
"Spouting nonsense is an end in itself."
We also have many examples of successful developing nations, from the USA to Japan, Korea and many others which all practiced heretical policies of protectionism.
Comparative advantage exists for trade within multinational corporations. They hire one dept here and another way over there and comparative advantage is the way that work X is done here and work Y is done there and the product is then exchanged
But all intracompany trade - and a shit load of global trade is intracompany - is priced arbitrarily. There's no arms length transaction and prices are mostly about where the company wants to shield itself from corporate taxes.
Comparative advantage is just a fact of life.
Hard to grow pineapples in Alaska.
But the existence of comparative advantage is just an argument in favor of lowering tariffs *all other things being equal*.
All other things are *not* equal.
To get to the desirability of 0 tariffs for a particular country is likely not possible given the inherent feedbacks of taxation, government benefits, and externalities are generally much stronger within a polity than between them.
"Hard to grow pineapples in Alaska."
True enough. But also true that it's hard to manufacture cars in America. We can stamp 'made in America' on the cars as they exit the factories, but as the components are manufactured in many other countries, the label is largely meaningless.
Most trade is absolute advantage. It's a big reason we have huge structural trade deficits. Though I suppose you could say that American banks have a comparative advantage in creating dollars out of thin air which is what then pays for products. But that's basically a bullshit notion.
A reminder for the economic illiterates.
"Free traders" oppose Adam Smith.
He generally favored tariffs to protect industries for national security and to offset local taxes on production, and on deliberation as a negotiating tactic to lower foreign tariffs.
Tariffs to offset local taxes on production is key.
Why should your neighbor's labor be taxed, or goods he sells you from his labor, but not the goods from foreigners?
That's not free trade, that's biased trade favoring foreigners.
Wealth of Nations, pg. 355, 356, 359
https://ibiblio.org/ml/libri/s/SmithA_WealthNations_p.pdf
Case 1
There seems, however, to be two cases in which it will be generally advantageous to lay some burden on foreign for the benefit of domestic industry.
The first is, when some particular sort of industry is necessary for the defence of the country.
pg 355
Case 2
The second case, in which it will generally be advantageous to lay some burden upon foreign for the encouragement of domestic industry is, when some tax is imposed at home upon the produce of the latter. In this case, it does seem reasonable that an equal tax should be imposed upon the like produce of the former.
Wealth of Nations, pg 366
https://ibiblio.org/ml/libri/s/SmithA_WealthNations_p.pdf