Raisin Farmers Fight for Crop Control
Supreme Court hears case of USDA agricultural takings.


Like characters in a Sergio Leone Western, government programs fall into three main categories: the good, the bad and the ugly. The program under inspection Wednesday at the Supreme Court fell squarely in the last category.
Many consumers like to eat raisins, and some farmers like to grow the grapes that are dried to make raisins. In a normal commodity, producers would produce as much or as little as they chose and then sell it to willing buyers. But raisins are anything but a normal commodity.
During the Great Depression, the government decided that prices paid to farmers were too low and undertook to correct the problem by limiting their output. Though that was an understandable response to the worst economic crisis in our history—not sound, but understandable—it has long outlasted the calamity that gave rise to it.
Today, the United States Department of Agriculture still assumes the task of deciding how many raisins should be sold—a job that in most markets is handled by consumers and producers continually responding to supply and demand.
When demand for product X goes up, for instance, prices rise, which induces consumers to buy less and producers to produce more, which in turn lowers prices. When demand falls, the reverse occurs. This system works so well that we rely on it for the vast majority of the things we need.
But not for raisins. For a long time, Marvin and Laura Horne grew their Thompson seedless grapes, which are dried to make raisins, and then did something unnatural: They kissed a lot of them goodbye. This was not by choice, but compulsion. They were required to give a share of what they grew to the government.
As one federal appeals court helpfully explained, "In order to participate in the world of raisin marketing, growers must surrender a portion of their crop as an entrance fee." Some years it's been 15 or 20 percent of their raisins; some years it's been nearly half. Some years, the government has paid farmers something for the produce, and some years it hasn't.
Dissatisfied with this forced arrangement, the Hornes decided to circumvent it by acquiring equipment to process their raisins and those of other farmers near Fresno, Calif. By becoming "handlers," they figured they would be excused from forfeiting part of their crop. But when they sold the raisins, the USDA slapped them with a fine of nearly $700,000.
So they sued for the simple right to farm raisins without carrying this onerous burden. The Hornes' lawyers argued that by confiscating much of their crop, the USDA violated the Fifth Amendment to the Constitution, which says private property may not "be taken for public use without just compensation."
This "takings" clause is what forces your state or local government to pay you fair market value if it wants to raze your house to build a highway or seize your land for a sewage treatment plant. The compensation requirement is a venerable bulwark against a grabby government.
But the USDA thinks the prohibition applies only to farmers' land—not the fruits of their labor. If that's true, argued the Hornes' lawyers, it implies the government "can take away one's car, furniture, refrigerator, books, silver and clothes" at its whim.
The Raisin Administrative Committee, which operates under supervision of the USDA, sells or gives away the raisins it takes, with the proceeds going to cover its operating costs, storage fees and promotional efforts abroad. If any money is left, the farmers get some of it. If not, they receive a heaping bushel of air.
You may argue that the entire program is a good deal for farmers, because it keeps prices up. In that case, you have to admit it's a bad deal for consumers, because, well, it keeps prices up. Regardless, it's a grievous affront to farmers who would like to pursue their lawful livelihood without being subject to annual confiscations.
The Hornes somehow don't see this system as a sophisticated and benevolent mechanism to help raisin farmers. They regard it as "stealing," as well as "a tool for grower bankruptcy, poverty and involuntary servitude." Marvin Horne told The Washington Post, "It's like being a serf."
He and his wife don't have to be told of the dangers of growing government forecast in Friedrich Hayek's 1944 book, The Road to Serfdom. The question for the Supreme Court is whether the road should have an exit.
Editor's Note: As of February 29, 2024, commenting privileges on reason.com posts are limited to Reason Plus subscribers. Past commenters are grandfathered in for a temporary period. Subscribe here to preserve your ability to comment. Your Reason Plus subscription also gives you an ad-free version of reason.com, along with full access to the digital edition and archives of Reason magazine. We request that comments be civil and on-topic. We do not moderate or assume any responsibility for comments, which are owned by the readers who post them. Comments do not represent the views of reason.com or Reason Foundation. We reserve the right to delete any comment and ban commenters for any reason at any time. Comments may only be edited within 5 minutes of posting. Report abuses.
Please
to post comments
Given the Court's tortured reasoning in Kelo v. New London I am not optimistic about this case.
"Though that was an understandable response to the worst economic crisis in our history?not sound, but understandable..."
Understandably evil.
A crisis caused and extended a decade by government intervention.
Understandable if you start with the premise that government must support stable prices, where stability means steady inflation.
See this inflation chart and notice how inflation rises during war and falls back after war. Prices were amazingly stable until after WW I, when the Fed prevented the normal deflation; the government only did less because Wilson had a stroke and no one wanted to fill in the lame-duck gap. Then comes the depression in 1929, and government did their damnedest to keep prices from falling as they would have in a free market. Never mind that wages did fall, and steady prices were the worst possible course.
That's where all these commodity boards came from, forcing prices to remain high, like treating a speedometer as a lever rather than a meter, thinking that high prices would encourage more employment.
It's the kind of stupid thinking that happens when government runs things and doesn't want to lose face by admitting mistakes, or lose power by admitting some program is worthless.
I just cannot find any possible reasonable way that this is not a taking. I mean, it's literally a taking! They're taking things! That's the very definition of the word "taking"!
Given that, I fully expect an opinion, written by Justice Roberts, upholding the government's conduct here.
+1 PenalTakingTax
You mean they can't? Victims of civil asset forfeiture will be surprised to hear that.
Didn't FDR take away people's gold at his whim?
Wait! You can grow raisins?
For a wesite called raisin...
The Raisin Administrative Committee, which operates under supervision of the USDA, sells or gives away the raisins it takes, ....
You may argue that the entire program is a good deal for farmers, because it keeps prices up.
As I pointed out in the previous thread, if they are selling or giving away the raisins, that defeats the purpose of keeping prices up. Prices are determined by supply and demand. If the government is putting the raisins back into the *supply* that negates the effect of taking them out in the first place.
Is there any evidence that the price of raisins is actually higher than the equilibrium market price?
All your raisins are belong to us.
* puts on stainless steel cup
Like characters in a Sergio Leone Western, government programs fall into three main categories: the good,
Citation needed for that last word.
My best friend's mother-in-law makes $85 /hour on the internet . She has been out of work for 5 months but last month her pay was $16453 just working on the internet for a few hours.
Visit this website ????? http://www.jobsfish.com