Unmanageable Care

Peering into the future is always risky business, and health care is no exception to the general rule. But if one prediction can be ventured, it is that there will be greater government control over the provision of health-care services in this country 25 years from now than there is today. It is only with somewhat less confidence that we can predict that this expansion of government activity will be a failure–regardless of the particular path of reform chosen by the Clinton administration during the next four years or (another prediction) by its successor administration four years hence.

The prediction of failure does not rest on the expectation of specific blunders beyond our current comprehension. Instead, it rests on broad principles. The physical rules of universal gravitation, applicable today, will be applicable tomorrow, and these rules predict that top-heavy structures are unstable and likely to fall when pushed. The laws of economics are not quite so inexorable, but they constrain the organization of complex social structures in much the same way that the laws of mechanics constrain the field of architecture.

Alas, the sad truth is that even the most talked-about current proposal for universal and comprehensive healthcare coverage– "managed competition''–contains within it the seeds of its own destruction. It is not so much a coherent government plan as an oxymoron. It is possible either to have managed health care or to have open competition in health-care services. It is not possible to have both simultaneously. That conclusion is based not on particular insights about health care but on general propositions about the uses and limits of competitive markets.

Competition does not take place in a void; it rests on a well-articulated system of property rights. The essence of that system is unchanged from Roman times to the present, and we cannot bend or ignore its basic logic to accommodate the political whims of our frenetic times. The key feature of property rights is that each owner has the absolute right to the exclusive use of his resources and need part with them only through exchange on terms that are mutually advantageous to him and to his trading partner. Starting from that secure base of property rights, each exchange moves the parties to a higher level of welfare–for why else would they consent to the transaction? At the same time, strangers to the transaction profit as well because their opportunities to trade are generally enhanced by the increased wealth of their potential trading partners. But there is no duty of any owner to enter into any particular transaction for the transfer of goods or the provision of services based on the need of the other party.

Once the basic property rights are in place, there is no plan at the center–no government monopoly–that prescribes who shall trade with whom and on what terms. In open markets, when a trade takes place, both sides are winners. When a trade does not take place, there is no reason to panic and every reason to believe that the parties have found more profitable avenues of exchange–unless, of course, the state has thrown regulatory barriers in their way. As Robert Nozick wrote (before his regrettable communitarian conversion), a system of voluntary exchange is totally antithetical to the achievement of any "patterned" outcomes, desired by the society as a whole or any dominant political faction. What emerges from the interplay of independent actors is a just distribution of goods and services not because of what it is but because of how it came to be.

Judged by this standard, any system of managed competition is a contradiction in terms. The ordinary system of markets does not seek to ensure that all individuals purchase health-care insurance, or, if they purchase it, do so in any fixed quantity. Instead, health care is but another good; from the point of view of the legal system, it is neither more nor less important than a good pair of tickets to the Super Bowl. We know of the importance of health care not from any government mandate but because of the willingness of individual actors to acquire it through contract.

We also know that for some people health-care protection may not be as important as it appears to us, for they have chosen to go without it, preferring instead some other use for their resources, be it food, shelter, education, or amusement. Long ago Thomas Hobbes stated what modern planners too easily forget: "The value of all things contracted for, is measured by the appetite of the contractors; and therefore the just value, is that which they be contented to give."

Managed competition does not work in this fashion. There is no option for any individual to leave the system. All must obtain coverage whether they want to or not. But the question is what counts as coverage. If the system simply required parties to obtain some health-care coverage, the mandate to insure could be met by purchasing limited protection–say, against exotic tropical diseases only. Yet universal health coverage is supposed to be comprehensive as well. Managed competition thus faces two unique challenges: First, it must specify a class of mandatory purchasers; second, it must specify a class of minimum mandatory purchases. It can survive neither.

In a voluntary market, persons have a choice not only of whether to buy health care but of how much health care to buy. With managed health care, however, people must purchase enough health care to satisfy the demands of a central planner. Cheap coverage only for some rare tropical disease is now conclusive evidence of an intent to evade the requirements of the universal plan. No longer can we obey Hobbes's injunction and let private appetites determine the scope of contractual rights and duties. The central planner determines whether firms must supply alcohol rehabilitation, sex therapy, psychiatric care, or a spare set of dentures. Those people naive enough to want coverage simply for bodily injury and disease will not be permitted that option. The choice is all or nothing.

These regulatory edicts on scope of coverage will not be made by independent professionals acting in the best interests of their own patients. Rather, they will be made by bureaucrats unable to fend off the sex therapists and alcohol rehabilitation specialists, who insist that no one can have "decent" health-care service unless their own specialty is added to the mandatory list. The motley collection of required services will quickly swell to the point where it becomes unattractive to consumers.

Now many Americans will face an unhappy choice: purchase health coverage that offers less value per dollar than that which could be acquired in a voluntary market, or do without. (People have been choosing the latter in large numbers during the last 10 years, responding to minimum requirements for health-insurance coverage established by many states.) Knowing pundits will chalk up the decline in rates of coverage to market failure rather than the regulations that choked off the market's vitality.

What happens to the millions who cannot enter or must exit the regulated market? Given the aspiration of universal health care, someone else must provide for the newly dispossessed. Because of managed competition, it is no longer possible just to remove the minimum coverage requirements so that some portion of the uninsured could filter back into the voluntary market. In any case, while this cost-reduction strategy will increase the market penetration of health insurance, it cannot work miracles. The perfect voluntary and competitive market cannot and will not provide universal health care: No supplier will provide care that costs more than its recipient can pay–period. Just as an insistence on universal automobile insurance leads to assigned-risk pools, so too managed competition must take care of its non-market participants.

But how? Here the alternatives are very unappealing. One approach is to raise the additional funds for universal coverage through a tax imposed on the fees paid for health-care services in the private sector. But this tax system will have to chase its own tail. Any tax on the health system will increase customer costs without increasing customer benefits. Those purchasers who value the mandated coverage more than its cost, but less than its cost plus the special tax, will exit the regulated system.

Even at the first stage the stampede to the exit is likely to be large if the tax is substantial, especially if persons without coverage in the regulated market can obtain it for little or no cost from the government pool. After the exit, the tax base will be smaller, requiring a still heavier tax to fund the government-controlled segment of the market. And so on with each turn of the screw. It is not at all clear that a taxed market and a subsidized market can survive side by side. The latter is likely to drive out the former, or at least substantial portions of it. The predator will then die because its voracious appetite has extinguished its prey.

One attempt to discourage exit from the regulated market is the "play or pay" proposal. The idea here is a simple one: Those firms that do not supply the minimum mandated coverage are required to pay a tax to the common fund. But how should that tax be set? If it is set too low, the world will have lots of payers, no players, and insufficient revenue for the government pool. If the tax is set equal to the cost of covering the firm's workers in the government-run market, there is a built-in shortfall: No money can be set aside to provide for the huge membership of unemployed persons who depend on the fund for their coverage.

Editor's Note: We invite comments and request that they be civil and on-topic. We do not moderate or assume any responsibility for comments, which are owned by the readers who post them. Comments do not represent the views of Reason.com or Reason Foundation. We reserve the right to delete any comment for any reason at any time. Report abuses.

GET REASON MAGAZINE

Get Reason's print or digital edition before it’s posted online

  • Video Game Nation: How gaming is making America freer – and more fun.
  • Matt Welch: How the left turned against free speech.
  • Nothing Left to Cut? Congress can’t live within their means.
  • And much more.

SUBSCRIBE

advertisement