The Volokh Conspiracy
Mostly law professors | Sometimes contrarian | Often libertarian | Always independent
How Did Justice Gorsuch Lose A Majority In National Pork Producers?
Thomas assigned the majority to Justice Gorsuch, but he couldn't hold five all the way.
National Pork Producers v. Ross is one of the more unusual Supreme Court splits I've seen in recent years. On its face, there are five votes to affirm. But the divide is quite fractured. There is no single controlling opinion. Justices in the majority and dissent have an unusually high level of agreement. And Justice Gorsuch seems to adopt two positions that are very much in tension.
Let's start with Justice Gorsuch's majority opinion. Part I provides a detailed history of food safety regulations, as well as the history behind Proposition 12. Part II provides an overview of the Court's "dormant" Commerce Clause doctrine. You can tell that Gorsuch is skeptical of these cases, but no one (here at least) urged the Court to reconsider those precedents. Part III rejects the so-called "extraterritoriality doctrine" and the "per se rule." (Chief Justice Roberts's dissent doesn't entirely disagree with Part III, but would adopt something short of a per se rule). In Parts I, II, and III, Gorsuch is writing for a majority. He is joined by Justices Thomas, Sotomayor, Kagan, and Barrett.
However, things go off the rails in Part IV. The five members of the majority do not agree on a single rationale. Part IV-A, which commands a majority, explains how the Court has followed Pike. So far, so good. The remainder of Part IV fractures into two camps. The first, conservative camp involves Justices Gorsuch, Thomas, and Barrett. The second, progressive camp involves Justice Gorsuch, Sotomayor, and Kagan. These two camps are very much at odds, and it isn't entirely clear how Gorsuch joins both camps.
The conservative camp joins Parts IV-B and IV-D. In Part IV-B, Gorsuch repeats over and over again that the Courts are not equipped to balance the "benefits" and "burdens" of state regulations. (I see shades of Bruen here--interest balancing is bad). And Gorsuch repeats, over and over again, that the Courts should not second-guess the wisdom of state legislatures. He would let Congress fix any commerce problems. It's no surprise that Justices Sotomayor and Kagan could not join Part IV-B. They think courts are equipped to balance these benefits and burdens. (Again, shades of the Bruen dissent). And Part IV-B is afflicted by Lochnerphobia. Justice Gorsuch cites Brandeis in New State Ice, Holmes in Lochner, and makes a terrible Herbert Spencer pun.
How should we settle that dispute? The competing goods are incommensurable. Your guess is as good as ours. More accurately, your guess is better than ours. In a functioning democracy, policy choices like these usually belong to the people and their elected representatives. They are entitled to weigh the relevant "political and economic" costs and benefits for themselves, Moorman Mfg. Co. v. Bair, 437 U. S. 267, 279 (1978), and "try novel social and economic experiments" if they wish, New State Ice Co. v. Liebmann, 285 U. S. 262, 311 (1932) (Brandeis, J., dissenting). Judges cannot displace the cost-benefit analyses embodied in democratically adopted legislation guided by nothing more than their own faith in "Mr. Herbert Spencer's Social Statics," Lochner v. New York, 198 U. S. 45, 75 (1905) (Holmes, J.,dissenting)—or, for that matter, Mr. Wilson Pond's Pork Production Systems, see W. Pond, J. Maner, & D. Harris, Pork Production Systems: Efficient Use of Swine and Feed Resources (1991).
I told you the pun was terrible. For what it's worth, Barrett articulated this position on Lochner and economic policy during her confirmation hearing.
Then we have Part IV-C, which Sotomayor and Kagan joined, which narrowly applies the Exxon precedent. If this case was clearly governed by precedent, then one would think that Gorsuch could command a majority on Part IV-C, and there was no need to write Part IV-B. But Thomas and Barrett did not agree with each other on Part IV-C. But Thomas and Barrett did not agree with each other on Part IV-C.
In Part IV-D, Sotomayor and Kagan jump ship, and Thomas and Barrett return. Here, Gorsuch responds to the Chief's dissent. He repeats the refrain that the Courts cannot reassess the "wisdom" of state legislation.
Justice Sotomayor concurred, joined by Justice Kagan, which explained why she did not join Parts IV-B and IV-D. She would simply find that the state did not impose a "substantial burden on interstate commerce." But Sotomayor would not cause "any fundamental reworking of that doctrine." The upshot here is that she asserted that Thomas and Barrett reworked the doctrine. Sotomayor would never even get to Pike balancing. This divide should have been apparent at conference, but perhaps it wasn't.
Justice Barrett wrote a three-paragraph concurrence. She agreed with Justice Gorsuch that the benefits and burdens of Proposition 12 were "incommensurable"--that is, could not be measured and balanced by the courts. And she did not think Pike requires "such a feat." But Barrett disagreed with Gorsuch, Sotomayor, and Kagan that the plaintiffs "failed to allege a substantial burden on interstate commerce." Here, Barrett agrees with the Chief Justices's dissent that there was such a burden. Barrett concludes, "If the burdens and benefits were capable of judicial balancing, I would permit petitioners to proceed with their Pike claim."
Let me try to summarize the score. Gorsuch, Thomas, and Barrett think that the benefits and burdens of Proposition 12 cannot be balanced, so California wins. Gorsuch, Sotomayor, and Kagan think the benefits and burdens of Proposition 12 can be balanced, and under that balancing test, California wins. I am confounded how Justice Gorsuch joined both camps.
Chief Justice Roberts wrote the principal dissent, which was joined by Justices Alito, Kavanaugh, and Jackson. There is much agreement between Gorsuch and Roberts. The Chief rejects the "extraterritorial" doctrine, and also rejects a "per se" rule. Roberts thought there was a substantial burden on interstate commerce. On this front, Barrett agreed with Roberts+3. In other words, five Justices found there was a substantial burden on interstate commerce, assuming you could even make such a measurement in the first place. Roberts would have remanded the case so the Ninth Circuit could have applied the Pike test. (Barrett would not have remanded, since she thought the Court was incapable of balancing benefits and burdens.)
What happened here? Let's assume that there were (at least) five votes at conference to affirm the Ninth Circuit, with the Chief Justice in dissent. In that case, Justice Thomas assigned the majority opinion to Justice Gorsuch. Now we know that Thomas and Gorsuch are big skeptics of the Dormant Commerce Clause doctrine. That assignment was "not an auspicious start." Gorsuch then circulates a majority opinion, and included Part IV-B. Gorsuch probably saw his analysis as a faithful application of precedent, and thought the Chief was wrong. (Wouldn't be the first time.) Thomas and Barrett agreed. But Sotomayor and Kagan saw red flags. Gorsuch adds what is now Part IV-C to keep Sotomayor and Kagan. But he loses Thomas and Barrett. After Roberts circulated his dissent, Gorsuch added part IV-D, which only Thomas and Barrett joined.
Roberts's dissent is especially conciliatory, and refers to the majority's "thoughtful opinion." By contrast, Gorsuch's majority takes shots at the Chief, gratuitously citing the Holmes Lochner dissent (which Roberts extolled in Obergefell) and Shelby County (which Roberts wrote). My suspicion, based on nothing, is that Roberts was able to pick to pick off one or more votes from Gorsuch. In other words, Gorsuch lost votes on Parts IV-B. Maybe Justices Alito or Jackson. I don't think Kavanaugh flipped, as he wrote a lengthy attack on California's burdening of interstate commerce, with a well-placed reference to birth control. He was locked in with the Chief.
Of course, take this speculation with a pound of salt pork.
Editor's Note: We invite comments and request that they be civil and on-topic. We do not moderate or assume any responsibility for comments, which are owned by the readers who post them. Comments do not represent the views of Reason.com or Reason Foundation. We reserve the right to delete any comment for any reason at any time. Comments may only be edited within 5 minutes of posting. Report abuses.
Please
to post comments
No need for courts.
Pork produces accept a short term loss of income by not selling in California.
When the bacon runs out, California residents reinstate the free market; at least in pork.
This blog post currently has a counting error in it: Justice Thomas did indeed join part IV-C of the opinion with Gorsuch, Sotomayor and Kagan. That still only brings that part of the opinion to 4 votes, when 5 is needed for a majority.
What is the pun?
I had the same question.
Well, that's how bad it was.
Thomas joined Part IV-C. If you can’t get something that basic right, why should anyone take this analysis seriously. I feel sorry for the students forced to buy your probably-inaccurate casebook.
"Here, Barrett agrees with the Chief Justices's dissent that there was such a dissent."
Say what? (And I'm not just talking about the extra "s" in "Justices's")
And another thing. Why is it inconsistent for Gorsuch to say both (1) plaintiffs failed to allege a substantial burden on interstate commerce and (2) even if they had, it could not be balanced against the noneconomic benefits the law is purportedly designed to promote?
So the answer to my earlier question is "threat."
No wonder the court has been so slow in releasing opinions.
Of course, take this speculation with a pound of pork salt.
Has Josh ever before expressed something this close to humility? Is he being held hostage in Orin Kerr's basement?
Yet here lies the problem with the current, legitimately constituted court and it's recent jurisprudence:
"In a functioning democracy, policy choices like these usually belong to the people and their elected representatives. They are entitled to weigh the relevant "political and economic" costs and benefits for themselves,"
In Masterpiece (decided on other, silly grounds), the people of Colorado said that they didn't want anyone in the state to be denied services based on their sex (orientation). But the court is fine with otherwise and will wield it's power.
I suspect that the recent legislation in Illinois and Washington to protect themselves against unstoppable ballistic violence will get the justices to intervene.
And I further expect that abortion rights laudably given to the states will be, with great sadness and reluctance on the part of the justices, curtailed
I thought Alito was somewhat famous for his love and defense of animals. I forget the opinions, but I know that there are some.
That love must confined to animals like dogs, and not animals that are like breakfast. It must be fine with him if they are never able to move.
It's a truly interesting set of concurrences and dissents that cuts across the usual/expected positions of the justices.
It would be interesting to read an informed, intelligent analysis of how that came about. Anyone got a link?
What’s hard to understand about different people agreeing that California wins for different reasons?
I was surprised that no justice mentioned the “original package” doctrine (aka the direct shipment loophole) that the Supreme Court adopted in regard to the interstate market for liquor prior to Prohibition; or the Wilson and Webb-Kenyon Acts (27 U.S.C §§ 121-122) that Congress passed to close this loophole. (This history is discussed at length in Part III-A of Granholm v. Heald (2005) and Part III-B of Tennessee Wine and Spirits Retailer v. Thomas (2019).
Until Congress intervened, this loophole allowed dry states to ban the domestic production and sale of alcohol but *not* the direct shipment to customers within the dry state even in the absence of economic protectionism or out-of-state discrimination (effectively nullifying the domestic ban). But the Wilson and Webb-Kenyon Acts are limited to alcohol so presumably the direct shipment loophole still exists, which could be significant when cannabis is legalized federally and Congress fails to in include language equivalent to the Wilson and Webb-Kenyon Acts in whatever cannabis legalization bill is finally enacted.
Do you think National Pork Producers, with its emphasis on anti-discrimination as the “very core” of the Dormant Commerce Clause, (citing inter alia Tennessee Wine) is silently rejecting the direct shipment loophole? Or that perhaps it still survives as a way of protecting the “instrumentalities of interstate transportation,” as discussed in FN2 of the Gorsuch opinion?
There’s nothing inherently contradictory about Gorsuch’s opinion. It’s not uncommon for majorities upholding a statute to say that a constitutional standard doesn’t apply, and it doesn’t apply for more than one reason, and if it does apply, then the statute passes it.
What I think everyone on this blog has missed is the likely extreme narrowness of this opinion. This case is likely to be just another “don’t say stupid things” case, a Mastpiece Cakeshop or Fulton of the Negative Commerce Clause.
What did all members of the majority actually agree on? This is the narrowest holding of the case and hence its actual holding. And it is this. Discriminatory intent is a required element of discriminatory intent, and Pike balancing, a kind of “discriminatory impact” analysis, exists only to provide circumstantial evidence of discriminatory, because intent often cannot be proven directly. But in this case, the plaintiffs explicitly disclaimed discrimination intent, rendering Pike balancing irrelevant.
So what should future plaintiffs learn from this case? Don’t disclaim discriminatory intent in your complaint. That’s it. If you simply plead discriminatory intent, Pike balancing remains open to you to provide circumstantial evidence of that discriminatory intent. And if these plaintiffs’ lawyers had simply done that, they might well have won this very case (Sottomeyor and Kagan might have gone the other way.)
So this is just another one of those “don’t say stupid things cases.” If lawyers aren’t stupid and make sure their pleadings don’t say stupid own-goal things in future Negative Commerce Clause cases, Justice Roberts might well end up assigning the majority opinions.
Sorry, discriminatory intent is a required element of a Negative Commerce Clause claim, and Pike balancing exists only to provide circumstantial evidence of discriminatory intent.