The Volokh Conspiracy
Mostly law professors | Sometimes contrarian | Often libertarian | Always independent
NIMBYism and Economic Ignorance
A new study presents compelling evidence that opposition to new housing construction is often caused the mistaken belief that it will increase housing prices rather than reduce them.

Zoning restrictions on the construction of new housing inflict immense harm by cutting off millions of people from housing, educational, and job opportunities. Even current homeowners who have no desire to move can often benefit from deregulation. Nonetheless, NIMBY ("not in my backyard") sentiments are a major obstacle to new construction and often block reform. The standard explanation for NIMBYism is that current homeowners rationally conclude that new construction is inimical to their interests, even if benefits society as a whole. But "Folk Economics and the Persistence of Political Opposition to New Housing," a new article by legal scholar Chris Elmendorf and political scientists Clayton Nall and Stan Oklobdzija finds that simple economic ignorance is a a major factor. It turns out that only a minority of Americans (about 30-40%) understand that new housing construction reduces housing prices, and a comparably large group actually believe the opposite: that new construction increases them!
Here is the abstract summarizing their conclusions:
Political scientists commonly attribute the underproduction of housing in US metropolitan areas to unequal participation and collective action problems. Homeowners, who are organized, repeat players in local politics, mobilize against proposed projects nearby, while renters, who would benefit from more housing, benefit too diffusely to mobilize for it and may not even vote in the jurisdiction. Using data from two nationally representative surveys of urban and suburban residents, we posit a further cause of the housing shortage: public misunderstanding of housing markets. Through vignettes describing a 10% shock to regional housing supply, we find that only about 30–40% of respondents believe that additional supply would reduce prices and rents. Using a conjoint design, we find that this "Supply Skepticism" is robust to question wording, stipulated counterfactual assumptions, and the cause of the supply shock. It also appears to be specific to housing: respondents generally gave correct answers to questions about supply shocks in other markets. Finally, we find that while nearly all renters and even a majority of homeowners say they would prefer home prices and rents in their city to be lower in the future, support for state preemption of local land-use restrictions depends on beliefs about housing markets. "Supply skepticism" among renters undermines their support for home construction, while some homeowners appear to be more supportive of new development than they would be if they held conventional economic views.
As the authors point out, "supply skepticism" caused by economic ignorance helps explain why renters often oppose new construction as much as homeowners do. The former have everything to gain and nothing to lose from lowering prices. But many don't realize that new construction will lead to that result. They authors also find that many homeowners actually want to see prices go down (contrary to the stereotype that voters are motivated by narrow self-interest). But, as with renters, many don't realize that new construction will have that result. The authors also do a lot of useful work to rule out alternative explanations for supply skepticism, other than ignorance.
These findings should not be surprising. For most voters, ignorance about public policy and its effects is actually rational behavior, driven by the infinitesimally small likelihood that any one vote will make a difference. Ignorance about the economic effects of zoning and housing construction is just part of the much broader phenomenon of political ignorance, which applies to a vast range of issues. I cover many of them in my book Democracy and Political Ignorance.
But Nall, Elmendorf, and Oklobdzija show that public ignorance about the effects of housing construction is much more common than similar misunderstandings about supply increases in other markets. They offer some possible explanations for the discrepancy.
The authors also find "a very strong tendency to blame housing providers (developers) for high housing prices. Conversely, actors whose stock in trade is opposing new development (environmentalists, anti-development activists) are almost never blamed." Ironically, ignorant public opinion puts the blame on the very people whose efforts tend to alleviate the problem, while sparing the real culprits.
Economic ignorance is not the only factor driving NIMBYism. Some people really do oppose new construction based on careful calculations of their narrow self-interest. While current homeowners can often benefit from development in various ways, if you're an owner who does not have children (or doesn't care about their housing costs), doesn't care much about promoting growth and innovation, and wants to ensure that the "character" of your neighborhood changes as little as possible, you might rationally oppose zoning reform, even if you understand its effects perfectly well. Historically, racial and ethnic prejudice has also been an important factor, though it has waned more recently, as education levels have risen and white suburbanites have become more open to integration.
But, while ignorance is not the only cause of NIMBYism, "Folk Economics and the Persistence of Political Opposition to New Housing" shows that it is likely to be a major factor. Reform efforts will need to take account of this challenge.
Economist Alex Tabarrok has additional comments on this article and its significance at the Marginal Revolution blog.
Editor's Note: We invite comments and request that they be civil and on-topic. We do not moderate or assume any responsibility for comments, which are owned by the readers who post them. Comments do not represent the views of Reason.com or Reason Foundation. We reserve the right to delete any comment for any reason at any time. Comments may only be edited within 5 minutes of posting. Report abuses.
Please
to post comments
This is odd. I always thought that opposition was based on the assumption that the values of their houses would go down. Am I in a bizarro world?
Captcrisis
Its a poorly worded opening/lead sentence.
Better explanation a few paragraphs down:
"But, "Folk Economics and the Persistence of Political Opposition to New Housing," a new article by legal scholar Chris Elmendorf and political scientists Clayton Nall and Stan Oklobdzija finds that simple economic ignorance is a a major factor. It turns out that only a minority of Americans (about 30-40%) understand that new housing construction reduces housing prices, and a comparably large group actually believe the opposite: that new construction increases them!""
ok thanks
Just to point out that 30-40% say that housing prices would decrease (the author's belief) with an increase in housing prices, another 30-40% say there would be no change, and the last 30-40% say there would be an increase.
This is not two-thirds saying there would be an increase.
And while I cannot find the raw breakdowns, it can easily be dependent on area. For example, in my local Northern Virginia, housing construction went up 8% in Q2, but housing prices went up 11%.
If you asked me what housing prices would be in 5 years in this area, I would answer "higher" in almost all circumstances - and that's not because I am "economically illiterate".
That said, when one of the cases was "more cheap housing in low price neighborhoods" and 30% answered "wealthy areas would get more expensive" I do wonder about the thought processes involved.
indeed. Many of these surveys often have 10%-20% or so of respondants who just answer randomly.
Also, was the survey of 'Americans' as a whole, and not of the NIMBY subset who actually drive the agenda?
It's possible that the NIMBY subset is representative of the whole, but my guess is that they're a bit more educated and calculating than people who potentially haven't given the subject a lot of thought.
". . . more cheap housing in low price neighborhoods"
I suspect that folks with lived experience in successful urban areas tend to discount that one to zero, as a contradiction in terms. Taking as examples Portland ME, Boston, New York, DC, Chicago, Seattle, Portland OR, San Francisco, or Los Angeles, can anyone point to conspicuous examples where that happened? If it does, it is rare enough to have escaped my attention altogether. I left out the South for lack of personal experience, but feel free to cite examples there if you know of them.
I would say, yes. The way urban planning agencies are set up, they are always effectively controlled by the owners of existing homes, who consider it to be the agency's job to keep home prices as high as possible, thus benefiting those homeowners (when they sell) at the expense of people who don't yet live in the community and thus don't get to vote on candidates who will run the agency.
In effect, urban planning is a cartel and ought to be broken up.
It's simply ignorance to believe that a personal home's value going up benefits the owner, because replacement houses, if they sell the house, also go up, and with the "value" increase is a tax increase.
People move to rural or semi-rural locations because they want that type of environment. Large scale housing development in that area brings everything they are trying to avoid right to them again. That's why most people support limiting development via zoning regulation. It isn't ignorance at all, they understand perfectly the effect of unlimited housing construction.
From my 10+ years on Planning Commission, these sorts of people are the majority of activists against re-zoning to "increase density."
Well, it IS ignorance, but it's ignorance on the author's part about the motives of people who disagree with him, rather than ignorance on the part of those people.
My own guess is that some of this reflects fear of gentrification. New housing attracts wealthier residents, etc.
A broader view of this explanation is that the expectation is based on simple observation - in areas where housing is being built, prices are rising. Of course, the causation there is backwards, but it's not hard to see why the argument appeals.
"We do't want poor people housing because it increases crime and drives prices down. Behind the scenes this is our opinion."
"We don't want mid and higher people housing because, although flight is the problem, reversing it is also the problem. This is our odd and contradictory but public opinion."
And new housing is nearly always more expensive per-unit than existing housing. Even when it's supposed to be low-income housing, in any big city increased regulations plus graft tends to elevate the cost higher than ten-year-old middle-class housing.
So it's obvious that the new housing costs more, and but you may have to do some research to see that the increased housing stock reduces the market price of old housing - unless you are sensitive to that reduction because you own some of the old housing.
Finally, it seems like most housing projects begin by bulldozing a poor neighborhood. That's definitely going to be a cost increase, whether individuals or welfare agencies will be paying.
I think it's true, isn't it? If an urban area starts gentrifying, typically because the local municipality created zoning or tax incentives, then not only is there expensive new housing built, but the value of the existing substandard housing units increases. It may be that the overall average price of the housing in the relevant larger urban area decreases, but most people don't want to move; they like their current neighborhood.
Agreed. It also can raise the floor while it lowers the average. For people who live in slums, average prices don't matter - just places with the absolute lowest rent. Of course, they're even less likely than other renters to participate in politics (ironically, I think local politicians in slummy areas work harder than average for individual constituents that reach out for help).
The problem with that idea is that the questions asked suggest certain specific cases, such as building more expensive housing or building cheaper housing - and both had a significant chunk of people that said housing prices would increase.
I mean, more than 10% of those asked said a lowering of the quality of life in a neighborhood would lead to increased prices.
Some results might have a logical thought process behind them, right or wrong, but some are just off-the-wall.
But I think you have the causation backwards.
It's not that residential development drives housing prices up, it's that rising housing prices in an area drive residential development.
It turns out that only a minority of Americans (about 30-40%) understand that new housing construction reduces housing prices, and a comparably large group actually believe the opposite: that new construction increases them!
The ignorance is in that unfounded assertion.
The question whether housing prices will go up or down after new construction is fact-specific. What is the character of the existing neighborhood? Is it a decent but run-down neighborhood of older dwellings, conveniently located, with ready access to a highly-attractive urban downtown? Likely it is also something of a rent haven, sheltering tenants who have been in place for decades, and whose rent increases have not kept pace with the market which exists—let alone the market which will exist after their neighborhood gets redeveloped.
I can point to multiple neighborhoods like that in the Boston area. They remain the only places where ordinary people try to raise families anywhere near the vicinity of downtown Boston.
What is the character of the new housing proposed? Almost always—regardless of set-asides or any kind of offsets—it will predominantly be market-rate luxury housing designed to attract the highest-income tenants the developer thinks he can sell to. That will set a new standard for the neighborhood, and become an opening wedge of gentrification which will in time—likely a decade or less—drive ordinary families out. The older dwellings will disappear, to enable maximally profitable use of the land they sit upon.
Where those formerly sheltered families will go, no one attempts to say. If Somin wants to find out about that process first hand, I suggest he get in touch with the surviving children of families which new development drove out of Boston's North End, and ask what happened to their parents.
That has happened time and again. It is a process tenants and landlords alike fully understand. Which is why they become competing factions over development questions.
It is really a bit much to insist everyone get neuralized to wipe out what they know from experience, and replace it instead with ideological economic cant which does not apply alike everywhere, or under every circumstance.
Exactly right. What Somin doesn't understand is that development doesn't increase the supply of land, it only increases the market value. And since land value is a major component of housing cost in urban areas, development is likely to increase housing cost.
David Ricardo (and Henry George) understood this, but modern laissez-faire advocates are considerably less sophisticated.
Actually, development, of high-rise housing at least, does in fact increase the supply of land, in the sense that the ratio of housing units to available land does increase.
What do you think drove the increase of housing costs in the North End? New development, or the convenience of the neighborhood?
bernard11 — Somin's argument is that supply increase drives prices down. High-rise development does the opposite to land prices. That seems to obviate an argument from economic principles that high-rise development is equivalent to an increased supply of land.
Bernard11 — New development.
In relation to its surroundings the neighborhood was unchanged. The neighborhood itself lost retail conveniences and amenities it had previously featured. The economic advantage created was an increase in housing supply to suit a professional class of tenants, in a location convenient to employment opportunities. Experience showed they were willing to pay higher prices to get that.
More people were housed. Land prices skyrocketed. Rents went up sharply.
The former residents of the neighborhood were mostly driven as refugees to outer suburbs, or out of the Boston area altogether. I afterward came to know several who had moved to the Providence area to find affordable rents, but continued employment in Boston by commuting.
The economic advantage created was an increase in housing supply to suit a professional class of tenants, in a location convenient to employment opportunities. Experience showed they were willing to pay higher prices to get that.
Stephen,
Exactly. There was an increase in demand for housing.
Do you really think prices would have remained unchanged as the area became more attractive to your "professional class of tenants" if there had been no new construction?
Do you think landlords wouldn't have raised rents, and that homeowners wouldn't have asked higher prices when they sold?
That kind of undercuts the claim of economic ignorance though.
If home prices will rise regardless of new construction, then survey results showing people saying that home prices will rise regardless of new construction isn't "economic ignorance", it's "pattern recognition".
Simply put, based on many people's lived experience, supply/demand is not a big enough force on home prices to overcome the fundamentals.
True in general, but the difference is not rise/not rise. It's rise by X or by Y. The new construction may well mitigate the rise that would otherwise appear.
The issue is, IMO, whether the new construction itself makes an area more attractive, or whether increased attractiveness leads to more construction.
There may well be some of the former. Maybe the new construction attracts more upscale retail business to the area or, to be not too cynical, suggests schools or police protection might improve. But it does not seem to me that this will be the main issue.
Mostly, builders want to build where they can sell their properties at good prices. I suspect they have very good noses for that. So it's the actual, or anticipated increase in demand that drives prices up and attracts construction.
Which is a different question then what appears to have been presented to survey respondents.
You know, that's an excellent point.
I instinctively read "reduce housing prices" as "make housing prices lower than they otherwise would be."
But of course that's not the question asked, as you say.
It is indeed quite probable that construction is correlated with rising prices - not because it causes them to rise but because rising prices stimulate construction - and that observation is what respondents based their answer on.
I do think that, under my understanding, there is a relative reduction, but I have to agree that it's hardly foolish to respond otherwise to the question.
If construction is restricted throughout a city and then heavy development is only allowed in a particular run down area that people used to avoid, then yes, there will be large rent increases for existing residents as demand increases faster than the new supply.
But if unrestricted development is allowed across an entire city, then such phenomena become less likely, less severe, and less lengthy. On average, the rent in the city as a whole will drop. Which means there is also an easy solution to temporary rent increases in new trendy areas, moving 5 miles in some direction.
GJW — This thread is a natural for the classic ideologue’s mistake to suppose you can reason from axioms to discover facts. In this case, economic axioms. Your comment is a pitch-perfect example of that mistake.
Few large cities in the U.S. feature the kind of city-wide freedom of development you posit. One of the few is Houston. Rents in Houston were up > 14% last year. Strikingly, at least since 1980 Houston’s rents have gone up faster than its population has increased.
In fairness to your larger point, Houston is about the best example around to illustrate it. Almost every other city—including the big Texas cities—fares worse. Unfortunately, that falls far short of the proof you need to counter a trend going in the opposite direction you claim it should.
A better argument might be that if only the U.S. had some systematic way to generate nationwide a housing boom priced to accommodate wages which chronically lag productivity, then supply-and-demand axioms might stand a chance. Nothing like that shows any sign of happening. Instead, rental housing demand shows every sign of behaving like highway demand—the more supply gets built, the faster demand increases.
Also, note the impact of new housing on commercial real estate prices and rents, due to new housing meaning more people living within walking distance of stores and restaurants.
This is a series of poorly worded arguments and discussions...
What you want to do is look at figure 4.4, on the right side. This starts to be somewhat informative. It's also a good look at surveys, and how they can direct responses.
Question 1: What is the effect of more housing in less expensive areas: ~27% - Makes rent (and prices) more expensive. ~25% - Makes rent the same price. ~48% makes rents lower
Question 2: What is the effect of more housing in more expensive areas: ~40% Makes rent (and prices) more expensive. ~30% makes rent the same price. ~30% makes rent less expensive.
Question 5: What is the effect of corporate buying on rents (and prices). ~80% Makes rent more expensive. ~10% No change. ~10% makes rent less expensive.
Question 9: What is the effect of more housing for "people like me" on "people like me": ~45% more expensive. ~20% no change. ~35% less expensive.
So, there's a host of stuff going on here, including the survey guiding responses. But gentrification I would hypothesize has a large role here. If new housing is going up, it's because there is more demand for housing in the area, and that's correlated with prices increasing and the area being more desirable. And that's what people see. Because, in general, cheap "new" construction doesn't occur. The cheap properties are the old ones.
Great, another "if you disagree with me, you are ignorant" post.
Is there a less persuasive form of argument?
Somin is just totally wedded to his thesis of political ignorance driving what he sees as poor policy choices. He sees almost everything through that lens and thus always finds something to support it.
People don't understand basic economic concepts like supply and demand. What a shocking discovery! I think our latest election results demonstrate that amply. We have an entire political party that claims a massive increase in the supply of money doesn't reduce its value. As Milton Friedman said, "If socialists understood economics, then they wouldn't be socialists."
Of course, Prof. Somin pretends that increasing the labor supply (through mass immigration) won't reduce the price of labor (wages), as if that weren't the very reason Big Business advocates it. So, I guess, economic ignorance comes in many flavors.
People don’t understand basic economic concepts like supply and demand.
Or perhaps the problem is that "supply and demand" is a very simple economic model that doesn't always match the real world very well. As a student and teacher of physics, I am acutely aware of the limitations of simple models of real systems. Frictionless surfaces, projectile motion with no air resistance, massless and frictionless pulleys all make solving high-school and introductory college physics problems doable in class. But the results of those calculations will get quite far from what actually happens as soon as those assumptions are not good approximations of the real system. For example, a penny dropped from the top floor of the Empire State building would be traveling 200 mph when it lands, if air resistance was negligible. But it isn't, and empirical results show that the terminal velocity of a falling penny is between 30 and 50 mph.
I expect that supply and demand similarly only obeys high-school Econ behavior in very simple markets.
Jason - The supply and demand curves actually do a very good job explaining economic behavior , even for very complex economic behaviors.
The problem is understanding micro economics is most people only account for very limited factors, such as only price or cost only taking a very simplistic analysis. A good example of typical analytical limitation is the supply of labor and wages. Most labor market analysis treats the labor pool as one large labor pool instead of the tens of thousands sub sets of the labor pool (even excluding the geographical subsets. )
Right. That is pretty much what I meant, though I phrased it poorly as suggesting that supply/demand itself was only a crude principle. The problem of the falling penny isn't that Newton's Laws aren't correct. (They are, except at relativistic speeds or at quantum scales.) It is that air resistance is an additional force acting on the penny, and it isn't just gravity pulling it down. And the force of air resistance increases with velocity, thus it becomes large enough to balance the force of gravity. The penny then stops accelerating. (Why it is called terminal velocity)
I'm sure that economic analysis is similar in that the results are only as accurate as the assumptions built into it, while the principles remain valid.
Jason - I will also add that many of the concepts in micro economics span multiple disciplines. For example, an understanding of micro economics, specifically the concept of marginal costs v marginal benefits would have provided an understanding as to why the covid mitigation protocols were never going to accomplish what was intended.
"A new study presents compelling evidence that opposition to new housing construction is often caused the mistaken belief that it will increase housing prices rather than reduce them."
This isn't even English.
If you include the idea of gentrification, maybe it is understandable.
Hence the value system you are expected to wear on your sleeve for all to see is satisfied. Meanwhile you also fight tooth and nail against low income housing, with attendant crime increases, behind the scenes where nobody can see.
“only about 30–40% of respondents believe that additional supply would reduce prices and rents”
Strange. I would have thought that homeowners would want housing prices to stay high or even increase, because they’d benefit from a higher resale price when they sell and move.
Homeowners generally want housing prices to stay high, up until they're looking to move. Once we're looking to move, unless we have a high level of equity, or we're moving to a much cheaper market, high housing prices hurt us as much as anyone else.
I bought my house before the market went up so much, it has about doubled in price, and I've got a fixed rate mortgage at a low interest rate. Life is sweet, right? But the moment I decide I want relocate it's going to turn sour, fast.
Renters? Pretty much never benefit from high housing prices. And about half the population rents.
I'm impressed with the thoughtfulness and civility of the comments so far.
NIMBYism isn’t primarily about economics. The new residents will vote, use the schools, drive, behave well or commit crimes, etc. This potentially can result in higher taxes, poorer education, congestion, worse services, and an environment generally inferior to that which residents enjoy.
Once you have enough money to meet your needs non-economic things matter a great deal.
Indeed, I live on the outskirts of Greenville, in what used to be a somewhat 'sleepy' bedroom community. People have been flooding into the area over the last decade, and an enormous amount of green space has been converted to apartments and condos. The resulting traffic problems have been horrific! The roads here simply aren't laid out to handle this sort of population density, and upgrading them to handle it will involve the destruction of a great deal of established homes and businesses.
The local government is enthusiastic, more population brings them bigger budgets, they're embarking on all sorts of projects they couldn't formerly have considered. But quality of life for existing residents absolutely IS declining in a number of ways.
"It's so crowded nobody lives there anymore."
I scarcely said anything like that.
I'm saying that it isn't economic ignorance causing people to oppose local regulatory changes that would drastically increase housing stock. A dramatic increase in housing stock locally can very negatively impact local standards of living.
There are several hours a day, week days, when a left turn coming out of our little subdivision is practically impossible. Accident rates have skyrocketed. The local city government's priorities have shifted considerably against the interests of homeowners, in favor of apartment dwellers. You can see this in zoning changes they're making which result in homes being unsalable because people can't legally live in them, and their not suitable for running businesses out of. You can see it in optional changes to roads to improve traffic flow, where there's little concern for how many people have their homes destroyed.
It's not ignorant of people living here to notice that. It wouldn't have been ignorant of people living here to have anticipated that. The people living here wanted to continue living in the sort of place they'd set down roots in, not to have it changed out from under them into the sort of place they wouldn't have chosen for themselves.
Ilya typically places no importance on the desire of people who already live somewhere that it remain the sort of place they want to live in. Whether it's a single family home suburb being transformed by high density housing developments, or a country that wants to control who immigrates. It's not so much that he argues other factors are more important, he just dismisses these concerns altogether as not worth addressing.
...and of course housing development also leads to further commercial and retail development to accommodate the needs of the new residents, putting further strain on existing systems.
quality of life for existing residents absolutely IS declining in a number of ways.
More precisely, quality of life for some long-term residents is declining. But why should that take precedence over the quality of life of newer residents?
Afterwards it doesn't. But if you're discussing people's expectations prospectively, (And how else would you be discussing expectations?)... They ARE the residents, at the time you ask them.
If you ask the people who already live someplace whether a change will make them worse off, and it does, they were right, even if it had the effect of making somebody else better off.
People rationally distinguish between their own welfare, and the welfare of others. Failing to be a universal utilitarian isn't a symptom of economic ignorance.
As a few of the more recent commenters have noted, looking at this issue from a too-simplistic perspective (eg., "supply v demand") will result in a too-simplistic conclusion. Don't forget that very basic tenet used by economists: "ceteris paribus" -- all else remaining equal.
In the real world, all "else" does NOT remain equal, and each survey responder (assuming that he is not just checking boxes to hurriedly complete the thing), has a separate and individual set of "else" on which he is relying to determine his response. Inferring meaning without deeper investigation is a fool's journey.
I mean, off the top of my head I can think of many examples where new construction was correlated with rising home prices for pre-existing residents.
I can also think of many examples where a lack of construction was correlated with rising home prices for pre-existing residents.
But the only times I can think of where prices dropped? It was correlated with some disaster (economic or natural), and was entirely distinct from supply/demand forces.
So call it “economic ignorance” if you want, but “prices rise regardless” is a repeatable and observable phenomenon.
Which is to say… in the real world, either the (A) downward pressure from increased supply in the housing market is sufficiently small that it will almost never overcome other upward pressure forces, or (B) the downward pressure from increased supply would drive down housing prices, but developers/builders almost always stop before that point, thus almost never leading to a real decrease in prices.
That housing projects devalue existing properties is an article of faith in every nimby anti-housing complaint I’ve ever seen. And I’ve never seen a court accept the claim because I’ve never seen anyone provide evidence to support it in an appeal. So I’m putting the “understanding that housing devalues property” down at 100% of the “Of course I support housing but this isn’t the right place for it” set.
I presume your statement refers to bringing in low income housing / sec 8 etc or any form of housing which is intended to serve a lower economic class than the surrounding neighborhood.
....and just what is the definition of "affordable housing"? What type of housing and affordable to whom?
"Affordable" always means "subsidized", whether this is an explicit government subsidy, a government project with units to be rented below cost, or a government forcing private projects to subsidize some units at the cost of increased prices on others. With all the increased costs required in new buildings by regulators, the only non-subsidized housing affordable by the lower-income 50% (or more) is _old_ housing that never had to meet those regulations - and usually some of that was bulldozed to make room for the new housing.
Studies! Aren't they great? What can't they do?
A simple supply-demand argument (more houses = cheaper houses) is too simplistic. It is, of course, true in the long-term after an equilibrium has set in. When a major new development breaks ground in an old established neighborhood, it often starts a cycle of gentrification for that neighborhood: attracting more development, raising the prices locally, pushing existing renters out, and changing the character of the neighborhood (which upsets long-time homeowners interested in maintaining the status-quo, not in taking the profits). In the long term, development is beneficial, and the alternative is blight. However, do not dismiss the real pain that is inflicted by ascribing it to ignorance.
There are many situations where what’s supposed to be generally true may not be locally true. Since we don’t live forever, the local situation is all we see. We’ve never seen stock market prices (or pretty much any prices) reach the long-term equilibrium posited by economists.
So, for example, while building new upper-class housing in a middle- or lower-class neighborhood may reduce the overall price of housing nationally, it may very well result in increasing the house of housing locally, hence the “gentrification” debate.
Would also point out that while ordinary people’s failure to see the results posited by economists usually leads to confident posts by economists about how ignorant and blind ordinary people are, every now and then it leads to economists rethinking their theories. For example, the idea that prices don’t inevitably tend towards long-term equilibrium, and fluctuations aren’t ignorable temporary phenomena but a permanent and non-ignorable part of the system, is now considered a respectable idea rather than mere evidence of ones of ones ignorance and low social status on the economist totem pole. It’s no longer quite regarded as a myth of the ignorant the way it once was.
Indeed, this business of confidently comparing what ordinary people claim to observe with ones theories is no longer quite the irrefutable evidence of ordinary people’s ignorance that it once was.
I know of no economists who posit that stock market prices (or pretty much any prices) will reach a long-run equilibrium.
Price equilibria are not going to be stable. Prices, especially stock market prices, change constantly. Even if there were no irrational or ill-informed market participants, and there are plenty of both, the daily flow of news would change prices constantly.
Disagree. Ceteris parabus if you increase supply, price will go down. But of course, all things are never held the same. Boston is known for its high real estate prices. This limits the number of people who move to Boston, and thus keeps demand down. If you increase supply, more people are going to move in - from outside. These people can bid up prices, and cause others to follow them - driving prices up still more.
Markets are funny like that. They change over time.
This is not accurate, Jon.
Let me don my economic pedant hat and say that a great deal of confusion over supply/demand issues comes from a failure to understand what those two terms mean.
They are not quantities, but relationships, curves, not points. Supply is simply the curve that describes how much of a good will be made available for sale at any given price. Demand describes how much buyers will purchase at any given price. The intersection of the two curves, if there is one, is the market equilibrium.
Economics has the bizarre custom of putting quantity on the horizontal axis and price on the vertical. Sorry, I can’t do anything about it. So the supply curve slopes up, the demand curve down. As prices increase, there are more sellers, fewer buyers. “Increases” in either are shifts of the curve to the right. So if supply increases the supply curve moves right and intersects the demand curve at a lower price and higher quantity.
So no, high prices in Boston do not “hold demand down.” They price would-be buyers out, resulting in less housing sold, but do not shift the demand curve. This is important because new construction does not somehow create the demand that drives prices up further. Rather it increases supply, pushing the supply curve to the right, where it hits demand at lower price and higher quantity than before.
Yes, this is a simple model, but it in fact explains a lot, and describes a logical, straightforward, mechanism that we can see working in our everyday lives.
Do prices influence your buying habits? Do prices influence business decisions on what products to produce, in what quantities?
The biggest argument against new housing construction is that it covers the ground, killing plant and animal life, and other organisms, and the means to produce food, that make us all healthy, and damages the collective mental health by reducing the observation of nature. Looking at it from a purely monetary economical viewpoint is egghead, nearsighted, ignorance.