The Development Dilemma
Can parking tickets explain why poor countries are poor?
Economic Gangsters: Corruption, Violence, and the Poverty of Nations, by Raymond Fisman and Edward Miguel, Princeton: Princeton University Press, 240 pages, $24.95
Many economists think corruption is a rational response to irrational incentives. The World Bank's "Doing Business" database lists 40 countries, from Iraq to Ethiopia, in which legally acquiring the necessary permissions to export a single standard cargo container takes more than one month. The more difficult it is to do something legally, the larger the temptation to do it illegally. Small wonder that in developing countries, few people make more money than customs officials.
If perverse incentives create corruption, that suggests a simple solution to an age-old problem. Hence for the last decade or so the mantra of aid agencies has been "institutions matter"āeven if it is not clear what humanitarians are supposed to do with this insight.
There is a popular alternative view that says corrupt countries are corrupt not because the incentives are perverse but because they're stuffed full of crooks, born and bred. In this view, corruption is cultural, and poor countries are poor because their citizens are dishonest (or lazy, or fools).
Into this controversy strode two economists, Raymond Fisman of Columbia and Edward Miguel of Berkeley, with a 2006 research paper that was brilliant and trivial in roughly equal measure. Fisman and Miguel realized that to test the two theories about corruption, you would ideally need to pluck people from all over the world, place them into a community whose laws they could ignore with impunity, then see who cheated and who was honest.
Impossible? Not at all. The United Nations in Manhattan kindly provided guinea pigs for just such an experiment. Diplomatic immunity meant that parking tickets issued to diplomats could not be enforced. The decision to park legally or not, therefore, was a matter of each person's conscience.
Fisman and Miguel found that countries with endemic corruption at home, as measured by the anti-corruption organization Transparency International, were represented by habitual illegal parkers. Chad and Bangladesh, so often near the top of "perceptions of corruption" rankings, produced more than 2,500 violations between them from 1997 to 2005. Squeaky clean Scandinavians, on the other hand, committed only 12 unpaid parking violations, and most of those involved a single criminal mastermind from Finland. On the face of it, this evidence supports the view that poor countries are corrupt because they're full of corrupt people.
Yet incentives clearly matter, too. In 2002, after decades of playing cat and mouse with the United Nations, New York City won much greater power to punish deadbeat diplomats. (The former New York senator and new secretary of state, Hillary Clinton, gets some of the credit for this change. Let's hope the world's diplomats don't hold it against the State Department moving forward.) The city began to tow cars and the State Department deducted fines from the relevant foreign aid budgets. Almost overnight, unpaid violations fell dramatically.
This is sparkling stuff, and the story is enjoyably retold in Fisman and Miguel's slim new volume, Economic Gangsters: Corruption, Violence, and the Poverty of Nations. I recommend the book wholeheartedly; it is engaging and confidently written, and it describes research of genuine interest. Yet while the parking ticket study exemplifies the authors' ingenuity, it also illuminates their limitations. I cannot be the only person to have admired the original research paper, only to put it down, reflect for a moment, and furrow my brow. We learn something about diplomats, but have we really learned something about economic development? I am still trying to make up my mind.
The other chapters employ a similar approach, taking a clever research paper by Fisman, Miguel, or both, and writing it up with an emphasis on storytelling rather than academics. Economic Gangsters tackles two big "institutional" problems of development economicsācorruption and violenceāthrough a series of vignettes based on research studying the value of political connections, smuggling between China and Hong Kong, the links between rainfall and civil war, witch killings in Africa, and rebuilding Vietnam after "the American war."
The book is bracketed by introductory and concluding chapters that loosely tie the story together and argue that the big debates about foreign aid and economic development cannot be resolved without careful empirical detective work such as that offered in Economic Gangsters. Summarizing one development controversy, for example, they conclude "both views are reasonable, but for now they're just theories. What we really need are better real-world answers. That's where our research and this book comes in." Such a claim is slightly misleading: While it's true that careful empirical work is needed to resolve these debates, and while it's true that Fisman and Miguel have done careful empirical work, it is not the kind of work that is likely to resolve the big controversies.
The Princeton economist Alan Krueger recently highlighted what he calls "tectonic economics"āresearch that studies seismic shifts in society. Steven Levitt and John Donahue's infamous research on abortion and crime is the canonical example. Levitt and Donahue concluded that the legalization of abortion had reduced crime rates almost two decades later, presumably by reducing the number of unwanted children. This shift is "tectonic" indeed: a sudden and wrenching legal change that seemed to produce significant consequences many years later.
According to Krueger, those who pursue tectonic economics do so "because of frustration that the randomized and natural experiments often give us a compelling answer but to a narrow question."
Fisman and Miguel, like all economists, try for both compelling answers and big questions. But when forced to choose between precision and scope, they choose precision every time.
That is not necessarily the wrong approach, but it is instructive to compare the young authors with two giants of the field, the charismatic Jeffrey Sachs (surely the world's most famous development economist) and Daron Acemoglu, winner of the rarer-than-the-Nobel John Bates Clark medal, given every other year to an outstanding economist under age 40. (The American Economic Association apparently has decided that the Clark medal is too scarce. In the future it will be awarded every year.) Sachs and Acemoglu approach the question of whether institutions matter in very different ways.
A decade ago, Sachs and two colleagues published research arguing that poor countries are poor in part because of their geographical disadvantages. Tropical climes encourage malaria; poor soil cannot be replenished without expensive fertilizer; potential markets are far away. And tropical, landlocked countries certainly do tend to be poor. Acemoglu took a different view, blaming institutions, not geography, for underdevelopment. The United States was once a developing country too, remote from potential markets. Now it is the market from which everyone else's isolation is measured. Remote Australia and New Zealand are prosperous too. Disease is not a geographical constant but something rich countries can fight; mortality rates in the disease-ridden American cities of the 19th century, for example, were appalling. Something happened to change that, and it clearly wasn't geography.
Acemoglu (with his colleagues Simon Johnson and James Robinson) does not deny that virulent illnesses have made their mark on economic growth. His contention is that they did so centuries ago. Tropical diseases, especially malaria and yellow fever, were so deadly to colonial settlers that the British authorities, under the auspices of the Beauchamp Committee in 1795, decided that Gambia and Southwest Africa were too dangerous even as a dumping ground for convicts. (They were transported to Australia instead.) In a Scottish-led expedition across Africa in the early 19th century, every single European died. Overall, 40 percent to 50 percent of European settlers in Africa passed away within 12 months of arriving.
For locals, these diseases were less dangerous. Acemoglu observes that local troops serving in the British army in India suffered mortality rates similar to those of British troops serving in Britain. But for British troops in India, death rates were five to 10 times greater.
In short, Europeans preferred to settle in the safer climes of what would eventually become Australia, Canada, New Zealand, and the United States. The Pilgrim fathers, for example, planned to travel to Guyana, on the northern borders of Brazil, before deciding that New England would be a wiser choice.
With colonists giving up on tropical territory, European colonial powers decided instead to establish highly exploitative institutions there, calculated to bring as many precious metals, ivory tusks, and slaves as they could in the shortest time possible. The settler-based coloniesāNew Zealand, Canada, the United States, Australiaāeventually became independent, with decent political institutions designed to respect private property and uphold the law. When the tropical economies became independent, their new political systems continued to suck out every cent of short-term gain and funnel it to the men in charge. Since political and economic systems are hard to change, the systems these former colonies have today bear a strong familial resemblance to the systems they had at independence. There are no prizes for guessing which institutions promote economic growth and which encourage corruption and violence.
The contrast between the Sachs/Acemoglu disagreement and the Fisman-Miguel approach is striking. Famous "tectonic" results, such as Levitt's findings on abortion and crime or Acemoglu's study of institutions and settler mortality, are fiercely contested by other researchers. That is not surprising: They are inherently open to challenge because of thescope of the question and the need for sophisticated statistical techniques and careful interpretation of raw data. Nobody is arguing about the statistical analysis performed in the parking ticket paper.
Instead, economists debate whether the behavior of diplomats tells us anything about what we really want to knowāthat is, how to fight corruption. Fisman and Miguel have their own bottom line: The parking ticket paper shows that "corrupt behavior is deeply engrained in culture and no small matter to root out." That's plausible but surely not proven.
It would be unfair to suggest that Fisman and Miguel are bonsai economists, producing beautiful miniature studies and little else. Their grander ambitions are most obvious in Chapters 5 and 6, in which they lay out evidence that drought or excessive rainfall leads first to famine, then to civil war and to other, more surprising forms of violence, such as witch killings. They convincingly argue that collapses in rural incomes helped trigger violence in Darfur, Chad, and Rwanda.
They then lay out the case for Miguel's brainchild, "Rapid Conflict Prevention Support." RCPS is foreign aid targeted at employing young menāthe most likely to take up arms in times of famineāand providing food to rural families, which are the most likely to kill off helpless old grandmothers and aunts when food is short. RCPS is humanitarian aid, but it aims at prevention rather than cure. Whenever rainfall patterns indicate that famine is ahead, donors send money to head off violence before it starts. And because rainfall cannot be controlled, dictators cannot manipulate it to win a larger flow of foreign aid. Fisman and Miguel believe that Botswana's long record of strong economic growth has been safeguarded by a domestic drought relief program. The idea may or may not be workable on an international scale, but it certainly does not lack ambition.
Overall, though, Fisman and Miguel's research shines a spotlight rather than a floodlight on development problems. Perhaps they're right to do so. Not everyone can be Daron Acemoglu or Steven Levitt, and it is surely better to answer a small question well than to answer a big question poorly.
Taking baby steps is not just a research strategy; it's a development strategy too. The aid skeptic William Easterly has complained that government bureaucracies would rather tackle a large nebulous problem than a small specific problem. Aid agencies' missions have thus crept from things that can be achieved and measured to things that cannot. Easterly dislikes the utopian rhetoric of Jeffrey Sachs and argues that development is better left to local, bottom-up, improvisational efforts that can be rigorously evaluated or (even better) subjected to a market test.
In their final chapter, Fisman and Miguel implicitly endorse Easterly's incrementalist view. They gently chide Sachs' hugely ambitious Millennium Village Projectāan effort that funds clinics, schools, new agricultural techniques, and other simultaneous investments in "model villages"ābecause it has not been set up to allow random evaluations. They advocate the use of randomized trials for small aid projects all over the world. Though this last chapter wanders away from the questions of corruption with which the book started, it is worth reading.
Such evaluation efforts, like the book itself, are necessarily piecemeal. Because a randomized trial offers compelling evidence on what works but not why it works, the lessons from such evaluations tend to be hard to transport to a different context. It is all very frustrating for big-picture aid evangelists, and it isn't much better for those readers who prefer books that offer grand concepts. Economic Gangsters contains none. Whether looking at corruption, smuggling, or outright violence, it is a fractured vision of a fractured worldāand all the better for that.
Tim Harford (timharford.com) writes the Undercover Economist column in the Financial Times. His latest book, The Logic of Life: The Rational Economics of an Irrational World (Random House), has just been released in paperback.
Editor's Note: As of February 29, 2024, commenting privileges on reason.com posts are limited to Reason Plus subscribers. Past commenters are grandfathered in for a temporary period. Subscribe here to preserve your ability to comment. Your Reason Plus subscription also gives you an ad-free version of reason.com, along with full access to the digital edition and archives of Reason magazine. We request that comments be civil and on-topic. We do not moderate or assume any responsibility for comments, which are owned by the readers who post them. Comments do not represent the views of reason.com or Reason Foundation. We reserve the right to delete any comment and ban commenters for any reason at any time. Comments may only be edited within 5 minutes of posting. Report abuses.
Please
to post comments
Great article!
Whoa, whoa, whoa. Didn't Karl Marx become fascinated by some tome written by someone... a Military General- I think- who postulated that civilization development was dictated by soil quality? And then Engles told Marx to leave it alone because the book was poorly researched or something? Gonna have to do some serious google searching on this subject.
Typo: the word "thescope" appears where it should be "the scope." Should be easy to do a ctrl-F find for it.
Really enjoyed the article.
Whether corruption results from perverse incentives or culture seems very much the chicken or egg question.
Fisman and Miguel have their own bottom line: The parking ticket paper shows that "corrupt behavior is deeply engrained in culture and no small matter to root out." That's plausible but surely not proven.
Or it could be that these people are completely above the law at home, and assume they remain above the law in New York.
An "elite" class of government functionaries who are immune from the law used to be an outrageous and alien concept, in this country.
Used to be.
"In this view, corruption is cultural, and poor countries are poor because their citizens are dishonest (or lazy, or fools)."
Duh, my neighbor down the road is poor because he's a lazy dishonest fool. Why wouldn't the same principal apply to larger aggregations of people.
This is why poverty can't be solved by external means; especially throwing money at it. You would have to convert a majority of the people into hard-working honest folk who make good decisions. Good luck with that.
Just the name makes me shudder.
A decade ago, Sachs and two colleagues published research arguing that poor countries are poor in part because of their geographical disadvantages.
Oh, for God's sake. Israel is massively geographically disadvantaged compared it its neighbors, yet is economically better off.
There's always Hong Kong, of course.
And, for laboratory examples of how geography is irrelevant, there is always the East v. West Germany, and North v. South Korea.
Fisman and Miguel have their own bottom line: The parking ticket paper shows that "corrupt behavior is deeply engrained [sic] in culture and no small matter to root out." That's plausible but surely not proven.
What this experiment shows is rather how people in each country regard property rights and not how infected they are with the corruption bug. These researchers focused their attention on people's actions instead of the why's. They made the mistake that Bastian warned about in "What is seen and what is not seen".
maybe some of whats called culture is responding to incentives.
When you could only steal films, music and computers by shoplifting the majority of people could safely say only scummy criminal people did that sort of thing.
Now everyone can download it easily and safely for free its acceptable.
I am not saying that shoplifting and illeglly downloading are exactly the same.
I posit that international welfare does huge damage to countries poor, often becuase it directly finances the regime perpetuating the problem (see: Africa). Implicitly, it seeks to do the same thing wealth distribution does at home, which I think is to eliminate risks by rewarding the status quo of the (perhaps) interface to the payor. Of course, that ignores explicit incentives, so I may have it all wrong.
RCPS is certainly a less-politically-sensitive way to do it, but it's still welfare. In fact, it sounds like a futures market. What's the matter with charity shares in lieu of all this? Some people are obsessed with government being large enough to fund anything, just in case.
Also: I have the sensation (based on personal experience) that, like the fall of Chinese bureaucracy, some people honestly and outspokenly support a thick web of laws of inconvenice in order to use their selective enforcement -- inevitable because of the code's complexity -- for their own gain. (I originally thought that's what this article was about, so I wound myself up on it and the last half of the article left me spinning.) However, I can't quite wrap my head around the faulty risk analysis for that in people in developed countries, besides to compare them unfavorable with tyrants.
I would say shoplifting and illegal downloading are the same thing. In each case you are enjoying the fruits of someone elses labor without paying for it (or obatining their premission to use it).
the U.S. is a great present case experiment. the last two decades government regulations have created such a buacracy that corporations have taken to buying politicians to get anything done.
Always remember the more laws you make the more lawbreakers you'll have.
Bootlegging copies is an old and profitable tradition. Which is to say, wholesale copyright infringement is as old as the reproduction technologies used (who would buy a Bible printed by Gutenberg when you could patronize a monestary and get several copies per decade?).
That's only part of the cost-benefit analysis: you skipped opportunity cost. By viewing a painting through a window and not paying admission to the gallery, is the creator losing out on something? Or, rather, are they risking losing one-time customers that are content with the window while risking gaining better customers who wouldn't have known about their work without the window?
To tie it in: in the same way that failing physical-reproduction-and-marketing industries use the courts to prosecute consumers, nee customers, for choosing a new supplier, governments... um, barrier to exit something laws enter but never leave or whatever.
If the owner of a gallery puts a paiting in a window, then they are in effect saying you can look at the painting through the window. Thus you looking at it through the window wouldn't be stealing.
Now, say someone developed some type of glasses that allowed you to see through solid walls, just because that technology existed wouldn't mean it was ok for you to use it to see the paitings through those walls.
Kroneborge, don't be dense. Can't you conceive of a gallery piece visible in the window that isn't the window's main display setting?
The point is that the volume of sampling a work, whether art or food at a stand or change in the leave-a-penny tray, can vary wildly; think of it as "demand". Enforcement can occur at any place along that access; think of it as the cutoff of "supply". You're not going to maximize surpluses by cutting off somebody's hand for tasting a single grape.
Personally I am not really certain on the whole intellectual property issue but i do think that lots of people who illegally download know that "it's not quite right" but do it because they can get away with it.
"Culturally" they wouldn't see themselves as thieves despite being easily able to buy the product.
I guess i am just saying can you easily quantify the difference between incentives and culture?
While we're flogging the whole IP thing again:
Whats the difference between making perfect copies of $20 bills and making perfect copies of a piece of (copyrighted) software, music, etc.?
RC,
Depends, is it a current fiat $20 bill or an old-school backed by gold $20 bill. š
The difference between shoplifting a CD and downloading music is that one is theft and the other is violating copyright. One is criminal, the other is civil (or was).
Not even remotely the same, even assuming you are okay with copyright laws. If, on the other hand, you see that copyright gas no place under natural law, then they are even more completely different.
Whats the difference between making perfect copies of $20 bills and making perfect copies of a piece of (copyrighted) software, music, etc.?
The piece of software, music, etc. has real value.
I liked the Goon Show episode, "A Strange Case of Diplomatic Immunity". The falling piano had DPL plates.
I think Hernando de Soto answers this culture/geography question much better in his book Mystery of Capital. http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Hernando_de_Soto_(economist)
The Development Dilemma implies climate, dependency from other countries, the lack of good institutions after colonization was over,the kind of people that discover the new territories in 1500, their values and what they come to do and to look for(Gold, raw materials exploitation,)and the treatment they gave to native settlers.After independency,ther was not a clear objective and the ruling class established itself by force and with interests in wealth concentration.Therefore the way to corruption was embedded in the process and in order to change that, war and polarization became the solution. If that violence had happened through civil war, with winers and losers and the former had had clear objectives to focus the socioeconomic process the results would have been very different from what they are nowadays.
"The parking ticket paper shows that "corrupt behavior is deeply engrained in culture and no small matter to root out."
Well I'd say the paper shows that corrupt people are send to the UN from corrupt countries which shows that you very likely need to be corrupt to get into such a position in these countries. I says nothing about those all the others.
Reminds me of the chapter in Hayeks "Road to serfdom": Why the worst come to power
Institutions matter very much.
sdgf
is good