Building a Better Bailout
How Washington could have helped the market at no cost to taxpayers. And what it should do if it's hell-bent on spending $700 billion.
Many observers are comparing today's financial situation—crisis is the preferred term—with the Great Depression, which included a four-year period when the American economy contracted by over 40 percent. To put that in perspective, second-quarter growth this year (the latest for which full data is available) was 2.8 percent.
Yet the comparison between today's situation and the Great Depression is apt, though not for the reasons many of those making it suppose: Virtually all economists now agree that the massive government intervention into the economy in the 1930s made things worse and significantly delayed financial recovery.
The $700 billion-plus bailout bill—signed into law in response to recent investment bank collapses and a lack of liquidity in the economy—will likely have a similar effect by distorting basic mechanisms that would allow markets to price securities accurately and efficiently. Packed full of tax breaks and "stimulus" treats to multiple special-interest groups, the bailout wishes away the fact that the current turmoil in financial markets is in large part the result of bad government policy.
In particular, the law does nothing to address easy-money policy by the Federal Reserve and unsustainable subsidies to homeowners and mortgage lenders. Instead, it assumes that bailing out the financial industry will do the trick. Tellingly, even the law's proponents acknowledge they have no idea of whether the bailout will work as intended. As Rep. Barney Frank (D-Mass.) said at the start of bailout negotiations, "We don't have a choice now of debating whether this is a good or a bad thing."
To make matters worse, there are several measures that lawmakers could have adopted—at no cost to taxpayers—that would have actually addressed the underlying causes of the crisis.
We know that a critical mistake was made by allowing financial institutions such as Freddie Mac, Fannie Mae, and investment banks to hold significantly smaller capital ratios than commercial banks, while implicitly guaranteeing certain banks' losses. Over the years, a series of rules were created allowing the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) to oversee broker-dealers, or companies that trade securities for customers as well as their own accounts. The capital ratio rule requires that firms value all of their tradable assets at market prices and maintain a cash balance equal to a percentage of that price weighed for the risk of each asset.
In 2004, the SEC allowed five firms—Lehman Brothers, Bear Stearns, Merrill Lynch, Goldman Sachs, and Morgan Stanley—to reduce their capital ratio by letting them keep more assets on their balance sheet while subjecting them to less reporting requirements. They now had an incentive to invest in riskier assets since their expected cost was reduced significantly.
Additionally, the only reason why the government-sponsored enterprises (GSEs) Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac were able to guarantee nearly $5 trillion in home loans with merely $100 billion in net equity is that both their management and other market operators knew that the government would step in if things took a turn for the worse. Acting as lenders of last resort, the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC), the Treasury Department, and the Federal Reserve Bank fueled the crisis by encouraging a decade of careless lending.
Under these circumstances, the capital ratio for GSEs and other investment banks should be raised at least to the level imposed on commercial banks—an average of 8 percent, depending on regulators' assessment of the bank's financial strength and the type of capital in question. Raising the reserve level would allow institutions to weather tight credit markets by having enough capital to face sudden increases in their default rates. The bailout bill does nothing to address this question.
What it does do, however, is bail out banks, raise FDIC limits to $250,000 (from the current $100,000 per account), and otherwise increase explicit and implicit federal guarantees. While these measures might prevent a panic in the short run, they are the seeds of the next financial meltdown.
Virtually all economists agree that one of the reasons for the current situation is that banks assumed too much risk by lending money they should not have. When the federal government guarantees bank loans or assets, banks have less incentive to evaluate loan applicants thoroughly, but they do have an incentive to engage in riskier behavior than they would otherwise undertake. When things are good, they make high profits and, in the case of a downturn, it is the taxpayers, not the banks, who foot the bill. Congress should return to more a disciplined banking regime devoid of guarantees by moving toward market-based deposit insurance.
One bit of good news is that the bailout bill reminds the SEC that it has the authority to suspend the Financial Accounting Standard 157, or "mark-to-market," which requires that companies value the assets on their balance sheets based on the latest market indicators of the price those assets could immediately be sold for. It's a sensible rule in prosperous times, but it puts otherwise solvent banks in a difficult position when they fail and sell their assets at low prices. Under mark-to-market, declining housing prices don't just reduce the value of defaulting mortgages. They reduce the value of all mortgages and all mortgage-related securities because the housing collateral protecting them becomes worth much less. Congress should have blocked them from going into effect in their stricter form last November and should have removed them formally in the bill.
The federal government could also have fostered savings and investment in the stock market by extending the capital gains and dividend tax cut past 2010 (when it is due to expire under current law). This would raise the rate of return of financial assets at little cost to the Treasury and give a strong incentive to taxpayers to stay in or go back into the market. Congress could also lift all Roth IRA contribution and eligibility limits for the rest of 2008. Because Roth IRA contributions are not tax deductible, this measure has no immediate cost to the Treasury, but it would have likely pumped billions of dollars into a tight market.
Such simple measures—raising the capital ratio requirements of investment banks, eliminating implicit guarantees to government-sponsored enterprises, suspending mark-to-market accounting back in 2006, and extending tax cuts on capital gains and dividends into the future—would have allowed the market to continue to reorganize its financial sector at absolutely no cost to taxpayers.
That being said, if the president and Congress were dead set on addressing the lack of cash in the economy, they still could have done so in a way that would have achieved the goal of injecting liquidity into the banking system while exposing taxpayers to far less uncertainty.
How? By taking the $700 billion they plan to give to Wall Street and sending checks worth $3,600 to the 191 million U.S. taxpayers. Such checks would then have to be deposited into some type of retirement account or be subject to the IRS's premature IRA distribution rules.
The most risk-averse people would invest this windfall into relatively safe money market funds, thereby preventing the credit crunch predicted by the pundits. Some would buy instruments such as mutual funds, which would sustain the market. Savvier investors, or at least those with a high risk threshold, would profit from the low prices on Wall Street to purchase stock in distressed banks.
Less than 30 days from the presidential election, such a measure would have proven popular with an electorate that does not trust the very politicians and technocrats who ignored the warning signs of a crisis and contradicted themselves constantly. And it would have prevented the socializing of a big chunk of Wall Street, a risky and unprecendented intervention into markets whose full effects won't be clear for many years to come.
Philippe Lacoude is the president of the consulting firm Algokian. Contributing Editor Veronique de Rugy is an economist at the Mercatus Center.
Correction: The original version of this piece stated that the bailout bill has suspended rules such as the Financial Accounting Standard 157, or "mark-to-market."
Editor's Note: As of February 29, 2024, commenting privileges on reason.com posts are limited to Reason Plus subscribers. Past commenters are grandfathered in for a temporary period. Subscribe here to preserve your ability to comment. Your Reason Plus subscription also gives you an ad-free version of reason.com, along with full access to the digital edition and archives of Reason magazine. We request that comments be civil and on-topic. We do not moderate or assume any responsibility for comments, which are owned by the readers who post them. Comments do not represent the views of reason.com or Reason Foundation. We reserve the right to delete any comment and ban commenters for any reason at any time. Comments may only be edited within 5 minutes of posting. Report abuses.
Please
to post comments
I want my $3,600!
Virtually all economists now agree that the massive government intervention into the economy in the 1930s made things worse and significantly delayed financial recovery.
Link? Because partisan leftist economists of the ilk of Paul Krugman (who are possibly the majority of economists) think that FDR saved the country with the fucking New Deal.
In fact, I recall that particular a-hole (Krugman) recently defending the bailout.
Rubbish - The 3600 dollars would have been largely spent on Chinese junk>
If the government gave everyone $3600 that they HAD TO invest, I would be sure to load up on junk bonds before the checks went out, and watch the prices skyrocket.
I think if we really had $700B burning a hole in our pocket, we should have built a massive water slide. It wouldn't fix anything, but at least we'd get a water slide out of the deal.
prolefeed,
Here is a link for you:
http://www.opinionjournal.com/editorial/feature.html?id=110010281
The bill only reminds the SEC that they have the authority to suspend SFAS 157. The SEC already had that authority, and the bill does not change that.
Having said that, SFAS 157 is a standard about the disclosure of fair values, and not the recognition of fair values. SFAS 115 is the underlying standard in this case. it is the standard that mandates that those securities you are not planning to hold to maturity will be reported on the balance sheet at fair value.
The authors comments about 157 reveal their ignorance. If 157 had been in place in 2006 (it wasn't) this crisis would have been revealed sooner and while it was a smaller problem. 157 is a huge improvement because rather than lumping all fair market values together, it forces firms to disclose which securities it has a market price for, and which securities fair values are based on estimates.
Your opinion would carry more weight, if you had the facts right.
Grade B- (highly inflated)
Dr B.
Yeah, those "savvier investors" are making a killing these days, aren't they?
Eliminating mark-to-market would only have hidden the problem better, not reduced it. The declines in home prices aren't just market fluctuations, they are a return to reality and likely to be permanent.
Many financial institutions aren't even adhering to the spirit of the mark-to-market regulations anyway. Since the holders of mortgage backed securities can't find any willing buyers at the prices they are willing to sell them for, there is no market. Absent a market, the banks left holding the bag are valuing them at "mark-to-model" -- what they think they should be worth, if there were a market. The fact that there's no market for them at present simply indicates that the holders haven't faced reality about their true worth.
I think if we really had $700B burning a hole in our pocket, we should have built a massive water slide. It wouldn't fix anything, but at least we'd get a water slide out of the deal.
Your ideas intrigue me and I would like to subscribe to your newsletter.
"When the federal government guarantees bank loans or assets, banks have less incentive to evaluate loan applicants thoroughly, but they do have an incentive to engage in riskier behavior than they would otherwise undertake."
Bingo! That's what I've been saying all along.
The reaction of the credit markets to the failure to bailout Lehman showed that the market players were expecting a bailout. The real analysis needs to take into account the real world implications of government interventions in financial crises. Without a clear understanding of what that role will be, it's hard to know exactly what investors are relying on in making many of their decisions. If they're assuming government intervention, one can assume that their decisions are different than if they weren't.
Again, we also need to know the actual assumptions that various parties in this crisis were relying on. If a government bailout is one of them, that seems very important to me to know.
The real question is whether or not government will intervene in situations like the current one. Without an answer to that, it is very hard to determine what will actually occur in the real world, or what a rational policy should be.
There's no point going on and on about the free market without knowing the actual assumptions and restrictions we're laboring under.
I've read both the links purporting to back up the claim "Virtually all economists now agree that the massive government intervention into the economy in the 1930s made things worse and significantly delayed financial recovery." and have yet to actually see any evidence in those linked pages.
Can someone - perhaps the authors of this Reason article - actually attempt to back it up? I mean, this is a pretty darn interesting fact that I'd like to understand whether or not it is, in fact, true.
Otherwise, it's just a huge Motzo ball just hanging out there...
I think if we really had $700B burning a hole in our pocket, we should have built a massive water slide. It wouldn't fix anything, but at least we'd get a water slide out of the deal.
Just one word: MONORAIL!
IRA penalties are only 10%
I would be at least half if not more of the reciepients then would just have paid the $360 in taxes and spent the rest. Sending the cash back over to China and the Middle East just like the rebate checks.
It's a sensible rule in prosperous times, but it puts otherwise solvent banks in a difficult position when they fail and sell their assets at low prices.
Maybe I'm misreading (or reading too much into it) but a rule that sucks in sucky times should also not be used in good times. One rule, one rule only Vassily.
Without mark to market investors can have zero assurance of the value of what they own.
For fun let's assume a pool of assets (could be a bank, a mutual fund, an insurance company, whatever) with two owners and no mark to market. The first owner thinks that the assets are probably worth significantly less than the quoted price so he sells.... What happens? If investor one is to be paid what he thinks he just sold for then investor 2 gets seriously screwed since the pool will have to have sold assets to fund investor 1 leaving investor 2 holding the (empty) bag.
It is not possible for investor one to be suddenly paid less: he sold at a quoted price .... the market would cease to function if nothing had prices associated with them. And whether this is the sell of a mutual fund or a bit of Lehman stock the net effect is the same. Which is why when the executives at Enron sold their shares knowing full well that the assets were worth much less than stated, we called it fraud.
And it does not matter if there are only two investors or hundreds. Mark to market allows participants to know what they are holding and what it is worth. Otherwise you'd get massive swings in holdings on the smallest rumor.
It is also a chain reaction: if no firms marked to market then they would not know what assets they held in any reasonable manner. Bank A could have X shares in Firm B which holds investments in firms P, D, and Q......
The bail-out should have been directed to the middle-market, entrepreneurs and small business. 95% of all employnment in the U.S. is owed to entrepreneurs and small business. Why do we band-aid those who have been the cause of the pain and not those who have been hurt by them. Lastly, the IRS needs to get off the back of the individuals and small business and out of the bed of big business. Put end to extreme and immoral penalties and interests that target those who can least recover from them. The IRS and Congress are the greatest impediments to economic growth and job creation within the U.S. Both need revamped.
"Under these circumstances, the capital ratio for GSEs and other investment banks should be raised at least to the level imposed on commercial banks-an average of 8 percent, depending on regulators' assessment of the bank's financial strength and the type of capital in question."
Help me understand this -- shouldn't the libertarian position be that the marketplace is smarter than regulators? Shouldn't libertarian philosophy be that the amount of capital on hand should be left up to the banks themselves rather than government regulators? What am I missing here?
What am I missing here?
That there is more than one flavor of libertarianism, each with different ideas about the legitimate activities of government.
You are not missing anything. I am afraid that we didn't make our point clear. The only reason why we think that lowering the capital ratio rules for these banks was a mistake is that we live in a system of fiat money where credit is derived from central bank "activity" rather than individual's real savings. In other words, we have lenders of last resort (the Treasury, the FDIC, and the Fed) that will bail out banks who fail rather than let them go bankrupt as they should. In a free banking system, there is no need for artificial one size fit all SEC rules. As you said in such a system "the amount of capital on hand should be left up to the banks themselves rather than government regulators." Sadly, we are not in such a system. We have a central bank, and it won't let financial institutions go under when they make mistakes.