The Entrepreneurial Solution
Business Plan for America: An Entrepreneur's Manifesto, by Donald Gevirtz, New York: Putnam's, 199 pp. $15.95
Seasoned individualists understand that there is as great a danger to freedom and individuality, and therefore economic dynamism, from Corporate America as from Big Government. More often than not, it is Corporate America that has encouraged the expansion of government and the regulation of commerce—to its own advantage, but to the stagnation of innovative growth. The corporate income-tax system has quite literally been designed by corporate lobbyists. Not surprisingly, it promotes conglomeration and punishes the entrepreneurial spirit of small business.
This is why Donald Gevirtz's book, Business Plan for America, is such a welcome contribution to the economic debate now raging in America. It reminds us that the vitality of our economic system is rooted in individual freedom. At the same time, it reminds us that corporate giantism is on the same deadly road to Leviathan as the socialist planners, who love the corporation's socializing potential.
As William Schambra noted at the American Enterprise Institute's December 1983 annual policy conference, "The tremendous new corporations created by the combination of modern technology and scientific management held out great promise in the minds of many 'New Nationalist' progressives. Walter Lippmann argued that the new corporation was the 'welcome beginning of a collectivist organization' holding out the 'possibility of cooperation' in place of the 'wasteful, planless scramble of little profiteers.'"
Yet without that "wasteful, planless scramble" Donald Gevirtz wouldn't have a story to tell, and the American economy would have created virtually no new jobs over the last 15 years, instead of the nearly 27 million it has created. Indeed, as Gevirtz points out, the Fortune 500 companies actually lost nearly 2 million jobs between 1970 and 1983. Unlike so many other participants in the industrial policy debate, Gevirtz does not interpret this decline as evidence of the need for government planning. Instead, he points out that "those Americans working in smaller-scale businesses with fewer than 250 employees climbed to nearly 70 percent of the total work force."
The plain truth, as Gevirtz's book makes abundantly clear, is that without the stunning revival of the small-business entrepreneur, this country would still be in the double-digit unemployment doldrums that have trapped Canada, the United Kingdom, and most of Europe. This revival actually began with the famous Steiger Amendment in 1978 that cut capital-gains tax rates from a high of 49 percent to 28 percent and was reinforced by the Reagan tax cuts of 1981.
Perhaps this focus on small businesses is not surprising coming from an individual who, as chairman of a commercial finance company, has helped capitalize over 15,000 small and medium-sized companies. But Gevirtz's approval of tax cuts and distaste for industrial planning is at least curious given his long-time close association with the Democratic Party. He was one of only two members of a high-level Democratic Party committee to oppose a 1984 recommendation that the federal government create a fund to help depressed industries.
Standing fast against a so-called industrial policy for America, Gevirtz urges instead that the country's entrepreneurial spirit be encouraged to flourish through less, not more, government economic planning. To support his case, Gevirtz notes that while "capitalism in most countries, notably Great Britain, France, and Germany, has become increasingly dominated by a fixed industrial aristocracy, in America, the individual entrepreneur has continued to challenge the well-heeled, firmly entrenched economic hegemony." Since 1980, including the deep and paralyzing 1982 recession, the United States has witnessed the formation of 2.4 million new businesses (using statistics through July of 1984). This is 25 percent more than even the extraordinary 1977–80 period and is the primary reason why we have seen nearly 7 million new jobs created during the current recovery.
In fact, right through the 1980 and 1982 recessions, the Small Business Administration found that companies with less than 20 employees enjoyed a 9 percent growth in employment and companies with less than 500 employees a 4 percent growth, while companies with more than 500 employees suffered a nearly 2 percent employment drop.
All of which is to say, as Gevirtz does so well, that the strength of the American economy today is more than ever the result of our traditional entrepreneurial spirit. Like supply-side economics, which focuses on the relationship between policy and individual incentives, this focus on the entrepreneur is a refutation of the "macroeconomic" view that has dominated the American "liberal" left for so long.
Gevirtz reminds us in Business Plan for America that the original economic dinosaur, John Kenneth Galbraith, wrote in 1952: "There is no more pleasant fiction than that technical change is the product of the matchless ingenuity of the small man forced to employ his wits to better his neighbor. Most of the cheap and simple inventions have, to put it bluntly, already been made.…A benign Providence has made the industry of a few large firms an almost perfect instrument for technical change." Another New Deal statist, David Lilienthal, warned that "as a nation we cannot live in the world of economic folk dancing and basket weaving and simultaneously in the world of the big productive machine.…Size is our greatest single asset."
As Gevirtz points out, these economic neanderthals were quite content to ignore warnings both from their right and from their left. On the right, economist Joseph Schumpeter predicted that the rise of the giant corporate bureaucracies would mean a "decline in the entrepreneurial function" and would dilute the normal process of "creative destruction" of old and inefficient plant. Austrian economist Friedrich Hayek noted that "technological progress in these last 80 years has occurred almost exclusively in the nonsocialist countries, and the former industrially advanced countries that have become socialistic have lost their technological leadership.…"
On the left, Lenin noted early on that "the strength of capitalism lies in the strength of its small business enterprise.…" Gevirtz infers that both Schumpeter and Lenin were far better predictors of the future than Galbraith or his Keynesian colleagues on the left.
Even as those industries dominated by "bigness" (autos, steel, plastics, etc.) began losing world market share at a dramatic rate in the 1970s, America's high-technology boom was being fed almost entirely by the individual entrepreneur. Under the influence of cuts in capital-gains taxes, America suddenly became again the venture-capital headquarters of the world.
Even that "industrial policy" guru, Paul Tsongas, formerly of the US Senate, was forced to admit recently in an astonishing discourse on the Senate floor, "that one bill, the Steiger Amendment, which I did not support, did more for the economy of my state of Massachusetts than all the things I voted for since I have been in Congress." It was a devastating admission that the incentivist and "micro" approach of the supply-siders was a far more potent means of producing real economic change than all the "fine-tuning" macroeconomic models of the Keynesians.
Unfortunately, Tsongas's recent Damascus-like conversion to entrepreneurial capitalism was not shared by his intellectual counterparts at Harvard, Robert Reich and Ezra Vogel, who have become the Galbraiths of the (fortunately) abortive "industrial-policy" movement of the 1980s. Vogel even suggested that "Japan with its group orientation, more recent emergence from feudalism, and government-led modernization has developed solutions for these problems [of economic stagnation] that America, with its more individualistic…history might never have invented." And Reich, in his industrial-policy manifesto, predicted miasmically that "it is becoming clear that America's economic future depends less on lonely genius and backyard inventions than on versatile organizations."
Yet all around Vogel and Reich, the economy of their own home turf, Massachusetts, is proving how wrong these advocates of industrial policy really are. The Massachusetts economy has been totally transformed, not by organization or governmental programs, but by literally hundreds of "backyard" inventors, software geniuses, and technological mavericks who have created burgeoning companies with hundreds of millions in sales, none of which even existed five or ten years ago. And they were spurred on not by the growth of government but by an unprecedented 23 percent decline in the Massachusetts overall tax burden, the direct result of a major tax revolt that the high-tech industry itself had fostered!
Even as total state and local government payrolls plunged by 35,000, the Massachusetts employment ratio soared to its highest point in history (and in the free world) at 64 percent of adult population, 4 points higher than in Japan, with an unemployment rate of only 4 percent. The Massachusetts High Technology Council had become the most vigorous critic of the industrial-policy illusions of the state's liberal establishment and the biggest thorn in Gov. Michael Dukakis's side.
Ironically, of course, the Japanese understand this. Not only does Japan have the lowest tax burden in the industrial world, with no capital gains tax, but one of its leading thinkers, Jiro Tokuyam, dean of the Nomura School of Advanced Management, told Gevirtz: "The entrepreneurial firms and the venture capital are the great advantages you have. If we cannot learn how to develop the Japanese entrepreneurial sector, Japan's companies will end up like the battleship Yamato at the end of the war, at the bottom of the Pacific."
One of the more interesting entrepreneurs to whom Gevirtz introduces us is Shunji Shinoda, who came here in 1972 as the management representative of one of Japan's biggest conglomerates and quickly found happiness in the American enterprise system, adopting the dangerous life of an American capitalist. He told Gevirtz, "In a word, Japanese society is one big bureaucracy, one big pyramid. Here it is different; there's risk, but it's not gloomy all the time. You can make your own future." Now, a growing number of observers are waking up to the fact that, largely as a result of the American entrepreneurial boom, America and Japan may be about to change competitive places, as more and more Japanese investors are pouring money into the US venture capital market where returns are high.
Through both anecdotes and crisply thoughtful analysis, Gevirtz spells out a "business plan" for the future of America that would refocus national policies away from state management or planning of technological expansion. Instead, national policy should focus on measures that release even more of America's enterprising spirit. Such measures would include making tax, monetary, and regulatory policy more accommodating to small business and less conducive to conglomeration.
A Business Plan for America is a genuinely "supply-side" treatise in the sense that it demonstrates the importance of how policy affects the incentives of individuals in the marketplace. Centrally manipulated government policies designed to stimulate the overall economy fail to appreciate the importance of the individual entrepreneur in the US economy.
This is an optimistic book that is refreshing in the wake of all the "industrial policy" prescriptions that have besieged us over the past few years. On a hopeful note, Gevirtz concludes that "by reintroducing the human factor into economic life, the entrepreneur may save capitalism from over a century of giantism and even greater depersonalization. In the face of ever-increasing corporate giantism and even against the threat of mammoth government and labor bureaucracies the entrepreneur has stood against history and survived."
Warren Brookes is a syndicated columnist and the author of The Economy in Mind.
This article originally appeared in print under the headline "The Entrepreneurial Solution."
Show Comments (0)