The Volokh Conspiracy
Mostly law professors | Sometimes contrarian | Often libertarian | Always independent
New Pew Research Center Report on "How States and Cities Decimated Americans' Lowest-Cost Housing Option"
They have done so banning or severely restricting low-cost "single-room occupancy" (SRO) housing.

The Pew Research Center has a valuable new report on how state and local governments destroyed much of their potential low-income housing stock by banning or severely restricting "single-room occupancy" (SRO) housing. Here is the summary of the report and its findings:
Low-cost micro-units, often called single-room occupancies, or SROs, were once a reliable form of housing for the United States' poorest residents of, and newcomers to, New York, Chicago, San Francisco, and many other major U.S. cities. Well into the 20th century, SROs were the least expensive option on the housing market, providing a small room with a shared bathroom and sometimes a shared kitchen for a price that is unimaginable today—as little as $100 to $300 a month (in 2025 dollars).
In the late 19th and early 20th centuries, landlords converted thousands of houses, hotels, apartment buildings, and commercial buildings into SROs, and by 1950, SRO units made up about 10% of all rental units in some major cities. But beginning in the mid-1950s, as some politicians and vocal members of the public turned against SROs and the people who lived in them, major cities across the country revised zoning and building codes to force or encourage landlords to eliminate SRO units and to prohibit the development of new ones. Over the next several decades, governments and developers gradually demolished thousands of SROs or converted them to other uses, including boutique hotels for tourists. And as SROs disappeared, homelessness—which had been rare from at least the end of the Great Depression to the late 1970s—exploded nationwide.
Now, as a nationwide housing shortage has pushed rents and homelessness to historic highs, some states and localities are reconsidering the value of lower-cost, small units with shared kitchens, bathrooms, and amenities. Ironically, had SROs grown since 1960 at about the same rate as the rest of the U.S. housing stock, the nation would have roughly 2.5 million more such units— enough to house every American experiencing homelessness in a recent federal count more than three times over.
As governments throughout the United States seek to fill the gap in low-cost housing, one promising and inexpensive model is gaining traction: making shared housing legal, as it was for most of U.S. history. And one version of shared housing—converting some of the vast supply of office space left empty since the COVID-19 pandemic—looks especially promising: A single office building conversion could add hundreds of low-cost homes near jobs and transit, while a large high-rise could add more than 1,000 homes. Several states have passed laws in the last few years to remove local legal barriers to building SROs or converting certain existing buildings into SROs.
This brief explores the history of SROs and their close relationship with homelessness. It also looks at strategies for adding large quantities of inexpensive housing units to meet the needs of the nation's most vulnerable residents as well as others seeking low-cost housing.
The report notes that studies show that homelessness is in large part caused by high housing costs, and that cities where low-income housing is more widely available (because they have fewer regulatory barriers to it) have much lower rates of homelessness. Thus, exclusionary zoning is a major factor increasing homelessness. I have previously written about this here.
The report also notes that one facet of SRO restrictions is laws banning or severely restricting the ability of unrelated people to live together and share the rent and other expenses. In a post about the Pew study, economist Alex Tabarrok calls this "the war on roommates." Fortunately, some states have begun to cut back these restrictions:
Perhaps the simplest method of creating low-cost shared housing is to allow unrelated individuals to share a house in the same way that relatives are allowed to share a house. But many communities limit the number of unrelated people who can live together—in some places, to as few as two. Such laws make sharing a house for a group of roommates—which usually enables rents lower than having an individual apartment—illegal. The U.S. has a record number of unused bedrooms, but many cannot be rented because of restrictions on house sharing by unrelated roommates, even if that would be the most profitable use for the landlord and the most affordable option for the tenants. To enable this low-cost housing option, Iowa, Oregon, and Colorado all passed bipartisan legislation to strike down local codes that prohibit house-sharing (in 2017, 2021, and 2024, respectively).
In all of those cases, states have stepped in when localities did not act, authorizing lower-cost housing and limiting the ability of local governments to ban inexpensive housing. The aim of those laws is to increase the rental market for low- and moderate-income residents and make more use of existing housing stock. If these bills succeed, and a large number of micro-units reach market, their rents will likely be low, since individual rooms, when available, usually rent for far less than houses or apartments.
Many readers have probably had the experience of needing roommates - sometimes more than one roommate! - to be able to afford housing in a relatively expensive area. These kinds of laws make it very difficult to take advantage of this cost-saving effect. Such saving not only make housing more affordable, but also make it easier for lower-income people to "move to opportunity," thereby expanding their future earnings and making our economy more productive.
In a Texas Law Review article published last year, University of Wisconsin Prof. Josh Braver and I explain why exclusionary zoning violates the Takings Clause of the Fifth Amendment, which requires government to pay "just compensation" when it takes private property. There, and in an Atlantic article, we explain how litigation should be combined with political action to break down zoning restrictions on housing construction. While we did not focus on SRO bans specifically, they certainly fall within the scope of our argument.
Editor's Note: We invite comments and request that they be civil and on-topic. We do not moderate or assume any responsibility for comments, which are owned by the readers who post them. Comments do not represent the views of Reason.com or Reason Foundation. We reserve the right to delete any comment for any reason at any time. Comments may only be edited within 5 minutes of posting. Report abuses.
Please
to post comments
Some rooming houses turned into dormitories.
The government can experiment with SRO public housing to see how it works today.
How about the government just butt out and let private parties "experiment" with a proven solution?
I am gobsmacked that Ilya has an article I agree with. Probably because he never once mentions two of his favorite bogeymen, and I shall follow that example by not mentioning them either. But someone will.
Ilya has been beating this drum as much as whatever you think are his two favorite boogeymen for a long time.
Gosh, read much? I said he didn't mention them. Can't I be grateful for small favors?
This is no longer a problem since the illegal aliens, "newcomers" in Ilya's jargon, are no longer coming to the United States.
This is also a Democrat problem since 42 out of 50 of the largest cities in the United States are not run by Republicans.
The solution to problem, don't elect Democrats to run your city or to secure the borders of the nation.
Yes, it is still a problem. Didn't you see those prices? The alternative without SRO is several thousand dollars a month when the city gets involved.
Is the problem really low cost housing for poor people? How about middle class houses costing way more than they need to?
Housing prices are already declining in areas with high illegal alien populations like California, Texas, and Florida, where 47.2% of illegal aliens resided in 2022.
The U.S. Census Bureau noted a decline in the median home price to $410,800 in Q2 2025, down from $423,100 in Q1 2025.
Are you actively pushing for a flophouse in your neighborhood or are you just arguing that it should exist as someone else's problem?
There are lots of problems with housing, especially urban housing but I've had enough of the luxury beliefs from those who only see what they want because they personally will never face the downsides.
Perhaps you don't know the difference between rooming houses and flophouses.
My wife and I live in coastal Massachusetts, where we own a 4-bedroom ranch-style home, with a full unfinished basement. Arguably more than we need, but helpful because it was a downsize after 30-plus years in a bigger place where we brought up our son. We ended up with a lot more stuff than we need, and it winnows slowly.
My son, by contrast, just ended 7 years living in extremely cramped roommate-shared housing in Somerville, MA—the customary, all-but-universal housing situation there. He indeed paid less in monthly rent for a tiny bedroom in a bug-infested building than we pay for our mortgage, taxes, and insurance on a whole house—nearly 15% less per-month than we do.
Basically, per-bedroom, the cost of housing in Harvard-proximate Somerville is only about 320% higher than where my wife and I live now. That's if you stick to converted 100-plus year-old ramshackle places in less-accessible neighborhoods. Somerville features some of the least accessible neighborhoods this side of Karachi. In Somerville, something closer to a subway stop is gonna run ya.
What Somin always leaves out of his housing calculus is the sales value of proximate amenities. Compared to almost everywhere in the nation, the place where my wife and I live now is paradise for natural amenities. Superb 4-season climate, featuring cooling sea breezes in summer, and warming ocean proximity in winter.
A short walk delivers some of the best surf-fishing on the Atlantic coast. Every autumn catches of 25-35 pound stripers become routine, along with 20-pound bluefish. A shorter walk in another direction delivers a fresh-water beach in a public park situated at a clear glacial kettle pond.
Local medical care is some of the best in the nation. For those with hard-to-treat rare maladies, the actual best is not far.
So why did my son pay so much more per-bedroom than my wife and I do? Simple. As amenities go, natural paradise is not a market match for Harvard Square.
That market-driven calculus will continue to drive the price of housing in major urban areas world-wide. It is a problem of geometrically-limited proximity to the best-of-the-best, as the world's richest people define the best (not usually by surf-fishing opportunities).
No amount of building, or even crowding, is going to change that market reality. Increase the quantity as much as geometrically possible, using all 3 dimesions; world-wide demand will always outstrip the supply. And those who can sell for more will remain at liberty to not-sell for less, unless rules against that dictate otherwise.
There are potential partial solutions. Improving central city accessibility with high speed rail to outer suburbs would open relatively vaster geometric areas to development at lower costs. Laws to cut foreign demand to zero would drive down rents a bit in deluxe urban centers.
For some reason, Somin never proposes such more-realistic solutions. The reason is that Somin, like many libertarians, is a market-theory ideologue, which rules out solutions which meddle with free markets. Unfortunately, it also rules out consideration of actual experience, whenever that embarrasses market-centric axiomatic theories. Somin is a rationalist, of the sort who so often demonstrate that rationalism does not always make sense.