The Volokh Conspiracy
Mostly law professors | Sometimes contrarian | Often libertarian | Always independent
How Exclusionary Zoning Increases Homelessness
A new paper by housing expert Salim Furth shows it does so by making it harder for marginal people to find housing with relatives and friends.

Homelessness has been in the news a great deal lately, and become a major focus of public debate. I've written previously about how homelessness is greatly exacerbated by exclusionary zoning rules and other restrictions that make it difficult or impossible to build new housing in response to demand. Much evidence indicates that the expansion of homelessness in recent years is primarily a problem of housing availability, rather than increasing incidence of social problems like mental illness, alcoholism, or drug abuse.
A new draft paper by Mercatus Center housing expert Salim Furth has a helpful discussion of how exclusionary zoning exacerbates homelessness. It does so by making it difficult for marginally homeless people to find housing with friends and relatives, which many could otherwise do even if they could not afford housing on their own:
In the United States, the primary definition of homelessness includes those who sleep outdoors or in a tent, car, or recreational vehicle, or who are in a homeless shelter or transitional housing provided by a homeless services agency. This often differs from the colloquial use of the phrase, which connotes a vivid human portrait: a person who has lived on the street or in shelters for a long time, who spends his days begging or loafing, who likely suffers indignities, abuses, ill health, and toilet insecurity, and likely has mental illness, a drug addiction, or both.
In truth, many of the people who a passerby might call homeless aren't homeless at all – they spend their nights in a home (perhaps an imperfect one) while spending their days in public. And many of the homeless are undetectable as such in daily life.
The American cities with the highest housing prices have the worst homelessness problems. YIMBY (Yes in My Backyard) advocates highlight this correlation to argue for policies that increase housing supply. But, when you think about it a bit, it's not clear exactly how high rent contributes to homelessness. It's not like $800 per month apartments are any more affordable to most homeless people than $1,000 per month apartments. And homelessness is frequently associated with mental health or drug abuse problems. This is why non-YIMBY progressives insist that only more generous vouchers or subsidies can help and non-YIMBY conservatives argue that only behavioral change can help by tackling alcoholism, drug abuse, and mental health problems.
The stories and data in this essay show the missing link between homelessness and housing costs: people without money who avoid becoming homeless do so mostly by staying with others, usually their own parents. This happens outside the formal housing market. But parents' and others' ability to offer space is limited by what they can afford in the market. Where housing costs are moderate, friends and family have bigger homes. When they are higher, friends and family don't have space to share, and this is often what puts a vulnerable person onto the streets.
Furth presents extensive evidence that a large proportion of the homeless are in this position. They are generally sane and able-bodied people who could find housing with friends or relatives, if housing were cheaper. Some could potentially live with roommates. "YIMBY" policies that make it easier to build new housing in response to demand could alleviate this problem.
The causal mechanism Furth highlights is highly intuitive. Unless you've been wealthy all your life, you probably have taken advantage of free housing with friends and relatives yourself, or know people who have done so. If, during that period in your life, you instead had to live in the streets, you would likely have been far worse off. Exclusionary zoning closes off this type of lifeline for a substantial population of relatively poor people, pushing them into homelessness.
Getting housing could also make it easier for these people to look for and find jobs, and - where necessary - improve job skills. Job-hunting and education are easier to do if you're not sleeping on the street! That, in turn, can make it easier for marginally homeless people to increase their incomes, thereby benefiting both themselves and the broader society.
In our recent Texas Law Review article, Josh Braver and I explain why exclusionary zoning violates the Takings Clause of the Fifth Amendment, which requires government to pay "just compensation" when it takes private property. There, and in an Atlantic article, we explain how litigation should be combined with political action to break down zoning restrictions on housing construction.
As Furth and I both recognize, increasing the availability of housing may not do much for homeless people who have severe physical or mental disabilities, or who engage in serious alcohol or drug abuse. But reducing the overall homeless problem could still help these people indirectly, by freeing up resources such as shelter space for them. And helping the able-bodied homeless is a great good in itself, even if it doesn't fully solve all homelessness issues.
Editor's Note: We invite comments and request that they be civil and on-topic. We do not moderate or assume any responsibility for comments, which are owned by the readers who post them. Comments do not represent the views of Reason.com or Reason Foundation. We reserve the right to delete any comment for any reason at any time. Comments may only be edited within 5 minutes of posting. Report abuses.
Please
to post comments
If only there were property rights, and you could do what you want with your 'own' home.
The more government interferes in the housing market the larger the shortage of housing.
In my years as a crisis center director I don’t think I ever had a homeless person/family who was unable to stay with friends or family due to lack of space. That’s not why they were homeless.
agreed - the vast majority of homeless have drug/alcohol or mental issues
True of many of the single people, but not the families. Perhaps zoning was related to their plight, in some indirect way. But typically they were evicted (after an adult lost his/her job, or the property was condemned/sold for redevelopment), or burned out, or victims of domestic violence. My experience was in the 1980's but I don't see why it would be much different now.
Maybe Simon should get in the real world
Stop by one of the street corners where they panhandle & talk to them
It would enlighten him
From years of attention to articles like this I see the root problem is not accepting certain root problems. So for Reason if it ever appears that some moral or spiritual soltuion is the answer, Reason sidesteps it.
Example : what is a CHIEF CHIEF cause of urban sprawl and all that brings in its train? Ans: Divorce
Another Example : what is a CHIEF CHIEF cause of pollution and climate change and all that brings in its train? Ans: Divorce
US national science foundation
Broken Homes Damage the Environment
A really inconvenient truth: divorce increases the environmental footprint of families
When Liu and Yu calculated the cost in terms of increased utilities and unused housing space per capita, they discovered that divorce eliminates economies of scale. Among the findings:
In the United States alone in 2005, divorced households used 73 billion kilowatt-hours of electricity and 627 billion gallons of water that could have been saved had household size remained the same as that of married households. Thirty-eight million extra rooms were needed with associated costs for heating and lighting.
Between 1998 and 2002, in the United States and 11 other countries (among them Brazil, Costa Rica, Ecuador, Greece, Mexico and South Africa), if divorced households had combined to attain the same average household size as married households, there could have been 7.4 million fewer households in these countries.
Around the year 2000, the numbers of divorced households in the 12 countries ranged from 40,000 in Costa Rica to almost 16 million in the United States.
In divorced households the number of rooms per person was 33 to 95 percent greater than that in married households.
To track what happens when divorced people returned to married life, the study compared married households with households that had weathered marriage, divorce and remarriage. The results: The environmental footprint shrunk back to that of consistently married households.
So, whaddaya gonna do? Ban divorce? Then more people won't get married with still separate households, or merely cohabit and then separate households after they break up.
The problem with zoning, in addition to it being a violation of property rights, is that it limits the ability of the free market to respond to housing demand, regardless of the source of demand.
True, but there's another reason. Many people become borderline-homeless because they have living habits that ruin the immediate area for others -- they are bad neighbors. Keeping rents high is often the only defense against having one of these ---s move in next door to you -- especially if he's in one of the demographic groups that make it possible for their members to file meritless discrimination claims and be believed.
"Keeping rents high is often the only defense against having one of these ---s move in next door..."
Then the free market will respond, without restrictive zoning, by certain areas becoming more expensive because they are safer thereby keeping the lowlifes out. Or, in response to market demand, proprietary communities will arise with no lowlifes and more of a guarantee of safety. Other areas would be cheaper for those who are willing to tolerate a few lowlifes.
Also when someone has a criminal record their options become practically non existent. We need to remove housing restrictions for former criminals who've paid their debt to society
In a perfect world, I would agree.
But what do you do with someone who has a history of arson? Extended drug use? Domestic violence? Child porn? A repeated history of bouncing checks?
There are a lot of variables, and while some landlords seem to go too far in saying they won't rent because of a shoplifting charge that happened 20 years ago, there are a lot of legitimate concerns when it comes to landlords and the people they rent to.
Presumably you would be for some sort of law such as "ban the box" but for renting. I would prefer the government stay out of legal agreements between two parties.
Totally wrong! Exclusionary Zoning, by which I mean that there are areas for detached single family homes areas for apartments, etc. People who oppose so called exclusionary zoning want to end the single family neighbors on the big lie there is a housing shortage.
Two facts:
(1) Every city that target single family homes as the cause of homeless, has at least ten times the space for multi-unit construction without touching single family areas.
(2) The homeless crisis was not caused by lack of construction but by the destruction of poor peoples' homes so that developers could construct high end projects in their place . The new units often stand vacant for for years due to lack of demand. Los Angeles, for example, has over 150,000 vacant units and about 44,000 homeless people. That is enough vacancies to give every homeless person their own apartment and still have 106,000 vacant units.
(1) Every city that target single family homes as the cause of homeless, has at least ten times the space for multi-unit construction without touching single family areas.
Reference please. Population tends to expand both upward and outward from the population center.
(2) The homeless crisis was not caused by lack of construction but by the destruction of poor peoples' homes so that developers could construct high end projects in their place .
Gentrification? The relevant question is whether more net housing has been constructed. Sure, if it is gentrification without net additional construction, it'll drive up prices. But, if there is a net increase in housing like, say, a luxury hi-rise in place of a few single-family homes, to fill those vacancies, the prices will have to be lowered, or kept from rising as much, so as to compete with and draw tenants from upper middle tier housing. And those upper middle-tier vacancies will be filled by lowering rents, or not raising them as much, so as to retain tenants, take back tenants from the upper tier, and draw tenants from the next lower tier, and so on until the market accommodates the new housing supply at rent levels below what they would have been in absence of that new supply. Housing is semi-fungible - an increase of supply in any tier will eventually filter its way around and lower, or keep from rising as fast, the prices of all tiers in proportion to the overall increase in supply of housing regardless of tier.
The new units often stand vacant for for years due to lack of demand. Los Angeles, for example, has over 150,000 vacant units and about 44,000 homeless people.
Do they? Reference please. At any given time there will be a certain amount of vacancies as people move out and new people move in. The question is whether those are temporary or long-term vacancies. I've not seen evidence that those vacancies are long-term as opposed to normal temporary vacancies.
It has been SOOOO good to have Ilya absent from Reason for a bit. I think he might have been suffering from TDS and had to take some time. Hopefully, he keeps his deranged posts to a minimum.