The Volokh Conspiracy
Mostly law professors | Sometimes contrarian | Often libertarian | Always independent
Legal Productivity, the Cost Disease, and AI
It has been a while since my last post on the Volokh Conspiracy. In 2021, I became associate dean at George Washington and did not have time to write. Last year, I switched associate dean roles and my portfolio became smaller, so I was fortunate to have some time to return to scholarship and to complete several articles. I'll begin my return to blogging by writing a series of posts offering shorter versions of the key arguments in a recently completed article that I have now submitted to law reviews, entitled The Cost of Justice at the Dawn of AI.
The article explores how changes in the productivity of lawyers affect the legal system and how legal actors should prepare for a future that may feature lawyers who are either more or less productive than today, depending in part on how artificial intelligence develops. The article's simplest claim is that the legal literature ought to pay more attention to the productivity of the legal sector, because changes in legal productivity directly affect the cost of legal services. Legal costs in turn affect how successfully the legal system can perform the core mission of ensuring that like cases are treated alike while cases are treated differently when applicable legal principles so demand.
The preeminent economic model for considering changes in the costs of goods and services over time is William Baumol's cost disease. This model is perhaps best known as providing an explanation for why the costs of college education and of health care have increased faster than inflation in recent decades. The essential story is that those sectors have enjoyed lower productivity increases than productive sectors like agriculture, textiles, or technology, and so products have become more expensive. Arguments that any given market is afflicted with the cost disease can be contested. Maybe, one might argue, educational costs have risen in large part because the core educational product—a professor lecturing in a classroom—has been bundled with increasingly lavish complementary services, such as ever-improving food and ever-increasing numbers of administrators to help students navigate their way through college.
Whatever the case for any given market, however, the cost disease story is practically tautological. When markets enjoy technological advances that increase productivity per worker, costs decrease relative to the costs in industries where technology has been relatively stagnant. If costs in productive sectors are falling relative to costs in stagnant sectors, then costs in stagnant sectors must be rising relative to costs in productive sectors. If we thus control for the overall price level, which depends primarily on macroeconomic policy, relatively stagnant sectors must become relatively more expensive over time. We can debate in any given market, including the legal sector, whether stagnation is occurring, whether apparent relevant inflation is attributable to the cost disease or to improvements in quality. But the very definition of productivity implies that if an industry stagnates, its products will become more expensive than other industries.
The article considers the implications of legal productivity both retrospectively and prospectively. The retrospective question is whether lawyers' productivity has stagnated, and if so, how has that affected the legal system. The prospective question is whether we should expect artificial intelligence to increase the productivity of lawyers and thus reduce the costs of legal services relative to other goods and services in the economy. These inquiries frame the ultimate question of how legal actors might prepare for a world in which legal services might be considerably more or less expensive in relative terms than they are today.
These arguments will unfold in future blog posts (and of course are developed in full in the article). For now, I will note two points from different parts of the article that highlight how considering productivity changes, past and future, may matter for understanding the future of the legal system.
In the past few decades, lawyers and legal scholars have observed a great reduction in the number of cases brought to trial, in both civil and criminal courts. This transformation has been referred to as the "vanishing trial," and the name is not hyperbole. The proportion of federal cases ending in trial has fallen by more than half in the twenty years since academics began discussing the vanishing trial in earnest, and declines have also occurred in state courts and in other countries. John Langbein argued in the Yale Law Journal that the vanishing trial is attributable to changes in procedural rules, and while that may be a partial explanation, it fails to answer why trial rates have declined so systematically, rather than only at times of procedural reform. Although commentators certainly understand that the high cost of legal services helps explain why cases settle, they have not considered whether increases in costs over time, potentially attributable to the cost disease, may explain the historic trends. Vanishing trials are precisely what one would expect from simple models of settlement bargaining in an environment in which costs are increasing.
The prospective point is that if the legal system has developed based on implicit assumptions about the cost of legal services, changes in legal productivity may change the balance of power in legal regimes. For example, legislators may allow for longer maximum criminal sentences than the legislators would think justice requires, if the legislators think that long potential sentences are necessary to give prosecutors leverage in an environment in which it is not practical for prosecutors to bring many cases to trial. Suppose, however, that AI greatly reduces the time that pretrial work takes, for example by efficiently sifting through evidence, creating trial plans, and assisting in the drafting of pleadings. Armed with a credible threat to take more cases to trial, prosecutors should be expected to exact higher sentences in plea bargaining. Judges will disagree about whether such a change is salutary or pernicious, but awareness of how changes in productivity may revitalize or upset established legal regimes is the first step toward conscious consideration of how the legal system should evolve following productivity changes.
But has law really been stagnant? And if so, will AI reverse this trend? I'll address these questions in the next two blog posts.
Editor's Note: We invite comments and request that they be civil and on-topic. We do not moderate or assume any responsibility for comments, which are owned by the readers who post them. Comments do not represent the views of Reason.com or Reason Foundation. We reserve the right to delete any comment for any reason at any time. Comments may only be edited within 5 minutes of posting. Report abuses.
Please
to post comments
When you lead with the prospect of AI I thought the recent verdict in the Midwest saying that real estate agents are overpaid monopolists. Computers made most of their skills unnecessary. It takes a better computer to make most legal skills unnecessary. That's coming.
(NYT headline: Home Sellers Win $1.8 Billion After Jury Finds Conspiracy Among Realtors)
Maybe, one might argue, educational costs have risen in large part because the core educational product—a professor lecturing in a classroom—has been bundled with increasingly lavish complementary services, such as ever-improving food and ever-increasing numbers of administrators to help students navigate their way through college.
>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>
That and theres a virtually unlimited money spigot pouring into it called student loans so they have no incentive to reduce prices or cut waste
Wow, here's a result I actually got from ChatGPT with the prompt, "write a will for a greedy rich guy."
Last Will and Testament of [Your Name]
I, [Your Name], being of sound mind and disposing memory, hereby declare this document to be my Last Will and Testament, revoking any and all previous wills and codicils made by me.
Executor: I appoint [Name of Executor], currently residing at [Address of Executor], as the Executor of this Will. It is my express wish that my Executor carry out the terms of this Will faithfully and expeditiously, without interference or delay.
Debts and Funeral Expenses: I direct my Executor to pay all my just debts, funeral expenses, and the expenses of administering my estate as soon as practicable after my demise.
Distribution of Estate: I hereby distribute my estate as follows:
a) To my spouse, [Name of Spouse], I bequeath the sum of [Specify Amount or Percentage] of my total estate, to be delivered within [Specify Timeframe] of my death.
b) To my children, [Names of Children], I bequeath the sum of [Specify Amount or Percentage] of my total estate, to be divided equally among them, or if any of them predecease me, to be distributed to their surviving issue, if any, in equal shares.
c) To my loyal servants and employees who have served me faithfully, I bequeath the sum of [Specify Amount or Percentage] of my total estate, to be divided among them in such proportions as my Executor, in their sole discretion, shall deem fair and equitable.
d) The remainder and residue of my estate, both real and personal, I direct my Executor to divide equally among my favorite charities, including but not limited to [List of Charities], provided that such charities are in existence and are recognized as tax-exempt organizations under the Internal Revenue Code at the time of my death.
Disinheritance: I hereby expressly disinherit any person who shall contest the validity of this Will or any provision hereof, or who shall institute any legal proceedings challenging the distribution of my estate.
Powers of Executor: I grant to my Executor all powers necessary or convenient for the administration of my estate, including but not limited to the power to sell, lease, mortgage, or otherwise dispose of any property belonging to my estate, without court order or supervision.
Governing Law: This Will shall be governed by and construed in accordance with the laws of [State/Country].
In witness whereof, I have hereunto set my hand and seal this [Date] day of [Month], [Year].
[Your Signature]
Signed, sealed, published, and declared by the above-named Testator, [Your Name], as and for his Last Will and Testament, in the presence of us, who, at his request, in his presence, and in the presence of each other, have subscribed our names as witnesses hereto.
Witnesses:
[Name of Witness 1]: [Signature of Witness 1]
Address: [Address of Witness 1]
[Name of Witness 2]: [Signature of Witness 2]
Address: [Address of Witness 2]
What, no survival clause?
😉
Cost disease perplexes me as an explanation of the high cost of things like education and medical care.
Here's my understanding of cost diease: Suppose we've got a world in which everyone either gives massages or produces electronic gadgets. Almost everyone wants more of both, so demand for both increases if price decreases.
Technology makes the production of gadgets much more efficient and less costly, so the price of gadgets falls. However, the productivity of masseurs doesn't change.
Since the cost of gadgets decreases, people can buy more gadgets *and* have more money left to pay for massages. They'll spend a greater share of their income on massages than on gadgets, but they'll have more of both.
That doesn't seem to be the case with medical care or education, both of which seem to be becoming less and less affordable. In a cost-disease situation, shouldn't people be able to afford more health care *and* more other stuff, even if they're spending a greater share of their income on health care?
The productivity of the masseuse doesn't change but the cost of the product (the masseuse's massage) can rise independently and negate the 'income effect', no? It's not a substitution situation.
I think it’s not really “the” explanation here, though it might be “an” explanation.
Look at the way house prices move in the opposite direction of mortgage rates; It’s the cost per month that’s actually the price subject to market forces, not the nominal purchasing price, so lower interest rates make buyers able to afford higher nominal prices, higher interest rates drive down nominal purchase prices because buyers can’t afford as much.
Apply that reasoning to education: Education inflation is a consequence of student loans with easy terms! If you had to pay cash on the barrel head for your education, or get a loan on NORMAL terms, education institutions would be forced to find ways to lower their prices in order to get customers.
Other factors reenforcing this are that a college degree had become an entry level credential for a lot of jobs, raising its value even if the degree wasn’t actually contributing to your capacity to do the job. And the decision to undertake the loan is typically made by people with little life experience, who don’t actually appreciate the burden they’re taking on.
But, cost disease? That hardly explains why they’ve been piling on all those extras, instead of stacking students like sardines in shitty dorms and feeding them dogfood, as was the norm when I was in college.
I guess I went to college about the time this trend started, though, because the dorms were improving, the university spent good money on a fancy sports center, (Pissing off students who thought it should have been spent expanding the library!) and they were just generally upgrading the experience in ways unrelated to actually conferring an education.
The reduction of the numbers of criminal trials has been astonishing during my years practicing law, which goes back to the mid 1970s. I think one factor has been the adoption of sentencing guidelines. Another might be the steady rise in the number of women as trial lawyers and judges. Also, the decriminalizing of many offenses done to make cases ineligible for jury trials or free attorneys has had an effect. It would be hard work to measure all of this.
A decade or two ago, the reduction was being attributed to the opposite. Penalties were so staggering it was said that defendants were willing to take a plea bargain rather than face decades in prison if they went to trial and lost.
So far as I can see, that's still the case. They're just gradually getting better and better at intimidating people into not exercising their right to force the State to actually prove the case before a jury.
In my state jurisdiction, there are numerous criminal trials—usually at least one going on at any given time in our courthouse of about 10 judges. Defense counsel in these trials are usually public defenders or high quality private defense attorneys. The defendants who, due to the public defender having a conflict, are appointed private contract counsel often plead guilty as charged because there is a strong economic incentive for the lawyers (who largely receive a flat fee) to encourage the client not to go trial. And the defendants who hire low quality private defense attorneys often lack the money to pay for representation all the way through trial, so they similarly plead guilty, often under unfavorable terms.
> numerous criminal trials—usually at least one going on at any given time in our courthouse of about 10 judges.
Back in the day, 8 of those judges would have been trying cases. There would have been about two prosecutors per judge to allow time for doing intakes, grand jury, trial prep, etc. But in budget lean times I worked in a prosecutor's office where the ratio got close to 1-1.
I remember trying cases as a law student under the student appearance rule in 1975 in a metropolitan county, where the judge and I would have 40 court trials scheduled each day.
Later, as a rookie prosecutor, I was in a smaller county where jury trials were scheduled tues-friday, and I remember trying four jury trials in four consecutive trial days (this would have been in 1979).
I am sure things were more hectic in other jurisdictions. I once chatted with a prosecutor from Detroit circa 1980 who told me that she was assigned one murder case a week.
Welcome back, Michael.
If this refers to Dunlop212, I also welcome posts like this.
“And if re-elected, I promise to do all in my power to help replace human inefficiency with Cyber justice in the courts of this county!…And I can promise you twice as many prosecutions at half the cost to the taxpayers…with modern, streamlined Cyberjustice!”
Frank Riley, “The Cyber and Justice Holmes,” Worlds of If Science Fiction, 1955
It’s worth a read.
https://www.gutenberg.org/cache/epub/59148/pg59148-images.html
.
White?
Male?
Right-wing?
Federalist Societeer?
The Volokh Conspiracy welcomes you back!
The law profession will never permit innovations that lower prices, least of all AI which it will use to raise them (faster, higher-quality work products, etc.). No change can possibly take place until the restriction on non-lawyers owning law firms is abolished and law firms are exposed to the tender mercies of private equity sharks, LBO practitioners, etc., just like the rest of the economy.
And in a striking example of synchronicity, a day after posting my comment I came across this: https://www.forbes.com/sites/brandonkochkodin/2024/02/26/why-law-firms-could-be-private-equitys-next-conquest/?sh=723e51052f5c.
There is already a substantial amount of litigation that fulfills no socially useful function. I feel that greater deployment of AI will simply increase this trend. I am pessimistic about the rise of AI for other reasons; as a young lawyer (specifically, public defender), I fear that the intellectual challenges that make the job interesting will go away if we have AIs to write motions for us and develop trial strategies.
AI will be like word processing. It will increase the amount of content that lawyers produce. Fewer cases may be making it to trial because the amount of paperwork generated per case has increased hyperbolically.