The Volokh Conspiracy
Mostly law professors | Sometimes contrarian | Often libertarian | Always independent
The Right to Defy Criminal Demands: Nuisance
I've just finished up a rough draft of my The Right to Defy Criminal Demands article, and I thought I'd serialize it here, minus most of the footnotes (which you can see in the full PDF). I'd love to hear people's reactions and recommendations, since there's still plenty of time to edit it. You can also see previous posts (and any future posts, as they come up), here.
[* * *]
A landowner creates an actionable private "nuisance" for neighbors if it foreseeably "significant[ly] harm[s]" the neighbors' "use and enjoyment of land," and its actions are "unreasonable"—i.e., if (to quote the Restatement (Second) of Torts),
- the gravity of the harm [inflicted on neighbors] outweighs the utility of the actor's conduct, or
- the harm caused by the conduct is serious and the financial burden of compensating for this and similar harm to others would not make the continuation of the conduct not feasible….
The question is … whether reasonable persons generally, looking at the whole situation impartially and objectively, would consider it unreasonable. Consideration must be given not only to the interests of the person harmed but also for the interests of the actor and to the interests of the community as a whole. Determining unreasonableness is essentially a weighing process, involving a comparative evaluation of conflicting interests in various situations according to objective legal standards.
And a business can be a nuisance because its conduct foreseeably leads to criminal behavior by third parties, such as its patrons.
This definition is broad enough to encompass situations where Danielle's business (or she herself) is known to be targeted for violence—perhaps she has already been attacked, either once or more often—and neighbors are afraid they'll get caught in the crossfire. Indeed, this is what happened in Governors Ridge Office Park Association v. McBrayer, where neighbors sued an abortion clinic owner for nuisance, partly on the grounds that
[McBrayer] knowingly brought with [him] a substantial risk of physical harm and property damage to [neighbors], [and] instilled a fear that a clinic of Dr. McBrayer might be bombed again, and their physical safety, lives and buildings might be threatened by activities such as the arson fire-bombing in May 2012 of the clinic in the Park operated by [McBrayer].
A jury awarded neighbors $1.5 million. (For an overseas zoning law analog, consider the Australian decision upholding a refusal to allow a building permit for a synagogue because it could be a terrorist target, given "[t]he threat situation with respect to Jewish communities around the world and Australia.") And the anti-abortion activist group Operation Rescue hailed this as a means for fighting abortion clinics more generally:
This case is important because it gives other office park associations a template to follow when abortion businesses move in and cause disruptions…. We urge office parks where abortion businesses are located to sue for nuisance they cause.
They (the abortion clinics) cause the nuisance, Operation Rescue was arguing—not the protesters (such as Operation Rescue members) who come to protest, or the arsonists who try to or threaten to burn down the clinic and thus endanger its neighbors. And while the Operation Rescue statement of course didn't urge violent attacks or threats, the logic of the decision created an incentive for such attacks or threats—after all, the office parks' suit for the "nuisance [the clinics] cause" relies in large part on the presence of such criminal conduct on the part of the anti-abortion movement's violent fringe.[1]
But the Georgia Court of Appeals reversed the verdict, relying in part on something like a right to defy:[2]
If we were to hold that a legally-operated abortion clinic cannot even operate in a commercial office park zoned for medical practices without constituting a nuisance we would be, in effect, holding that such clinics cannot properly operate anywhere. As [amici curiae] correctly point out, such a holding could be used to expose a broad array of legal businesses and institutions to nuisance liability due to the fact that some find them controversial and some will protest their very existence.
Both legal protestors and criminals have caused disruption around a multitude of business and institutions, such as gun shops, fur retailers, Chick-Fil-A restaurants, police departments, synagogues, statehouses, Black churches, adult entertainment establishments, and mosques, to name a few. Under the common law, property ownership in Georgia does not guarantee only ideologically-aligned neighbors whose business practices will cause no upset or attract no controversy, and we will not hold otherwise.[3]
One way of fitting this with similar rules in negligence law is as an implicit holding that refusing to go along with criminals' demands is per se not "unreasonable"; to quote the Restatement,
In respect to certain types of intentional invasion, there has been a crystallization of legal opinion as to gravity and utility, with the result that the invasions are held to be reasonable or unreasonable as a matter of law…. [Thus,] a series of judicial decisions may establish a rule of law to the effect that certain types of interference with residential uses of land in strictly residential districts constitute unreasonable invasions when the interferences are caused by public garages, mortuaries or some other particular type of business enterprise.
[1] To be sure, the legal system does try to diminish such incentives in other ways, for instance by criminally punishing the attacks or threats (though note that anonymous threats can be very hard to track down and therefore punish), or by enhancing the sentence for such behavior when it is aimed at preventing certain important activities. But I think the legal system should still try to avoid increasing such incentives.
[2] The court also concluded that, under Georgia law, nuisance liability for the misbehavior of third parties may require a showing of "control" over those parties, and thus be limited to misbehavior by people who are or have been the business's patrons—not by the business's enemies.
[3] The cited amicus brief was filed by me, together with local counsel Darren Summerville, on behalf of various law professors, a First Amendment advocacy group, and a Second Amendment advocacy group.
Editor's Note: We invite comments and request that they be civil and on-topic. We do not moderate or assume any responsibility for comments, which are owned by the readers who post them. Comments do not represent the views of Reason.com or Reason Foundation. We reserve the right to delete any comment for any reason at any time. Comments may only be edited within 5 minutes of posting. Report abuses.
Please
to post comments
I think there’s a very clear standard for my exception.
Can the state prohibit the thing in the first place?
If it can prohibit it in the first place, directly, it can impose third-party liability.
It can impose third party liability without a direct prohibition it wants. Such a policy is an analog of enforce upon complaint - you can do it as long as nobody gets upset by it. Here, you can do it as long as nobody gets hurt.
So this poses a straightforward way of dealing with the abortion clinic case. Since you can’t ban the abortion clinoc directly, you can’t inpose third-party liability.
But if Roe were completely reversed, and the state could ban abortion clinics directly, a state absolutely could impose a requirement that they locate only in out/of-the-way places where no third party gets hurt by people protesting them. It absolutely could impose third party liability. And it could do this as a compromise solution between complete legalization and complete vanning.
It’s a way of keeping the peace. And keeping the peace, which can sometimes involve tolerating something but only as long as it doesn’t lead to a disturbance, is a completely rational basis for legislation in situations where people have strong disagreements and strong feelings about things. It’s a potential compromise policy solution a state should be allowed to have if it wants, especially in an era when compromises on divisive issues seem hard to come by.
Compromise often seems inconsistent, irrational. But this is foolishness, a hobgoblin of little minds. Methods that keep the peace and avoid destructive divisions in society in the face of bitter disagreement are worth a little inconsistency. And they aren’t nearly so irrational as they might seem.
Eh? I am confused.
If abortion were illegal, the state wouldn't need to also to ban abortion clinics. And the idea that the state could relegate abortion clinics to out of the way places makes even less sense.
IANAL. What legal quibble have I misunderstood?
If Roe were reversed, abortion would not become illegal automatically (except in states that have abortion prohibitions on the books already, but which have been unenforceable under the Roe standard).
Ah, I knew that, but had ignored it in this context, thinking ReaderY meant reversed, as in, made illegal altogether, not just that conditions would revert to states controlling it.
My apologies, ReaderY.
Let’s look at prostitution, which states can criminalize. Some states ban prostitution but have no law specifically banning brothels. A few states have had laws that do the opposite, banning brothels but not specifically banning prostitution. And Nevada, which has legalized both, requires brothels to locate in relatively out of the way places.
A state absolutely could have a legal regime in which prostitution is generally legal, but if someone gets damaged by an altercation with an irate spouse, protesters, etc., there’s liability for it.
It could also have a regime in which prostitution isn’t a crime but is subject to the law of nuisance, so if the neighbors don’t like it, the brothel has to move, effectively requiring brothels to locate in friendly and/or out-of-the-way areas.
Abortion would be no different if Roe v. Wade was completely reversed.
And regarding the “makes even less sense” part - this is something I’ve been raising in my comments on Professor Volokh’s blog for many years. It is often in the nature of compromises that they don’t make sense. A compromise represents an option between two logically consistent, dynamically opposed perspectives, each making sense in its own world. If you think killing a fetus is murder, allowing abortion clinics at all makes no sense, it’s letting the criminals win. If you think abortion is a fundamental right, relegating abortion clinics to out of the way places and allowing a protester veto makes no sense, it’s letting the criminals win.
It’s in the nature of compromises that they speak to a world where nobody is regarded as completely a criminal and everybody is allowed to win a little bit. Such a world may make no sense. It doesn’t satisfy anyone. And yet it is sometimes ressonable for a society faced with a very long-term disagreement to organize itself this way, to leave everyone a little bit dissatisfied and nobody dead.
Sometimes remaining alive and keeping the peace has more value than making perfect sense. Sometimes perfect comsistency is not the wisest course of action.
Part of my concern with Professor Volokh’s title choice is that the very question of who is the criminal - the people doing the action or the people protesting and trying to stop it - will always depend on which side you’re on. There are times when society has changed sides. But there are also times when it might be best if it doesn’t side completely with either side. While neither side may find that this option makes sense, the ability to do it needs to be preserved.
This also addresses a conflict between rationalism and empiricism. Rationalism is aboit what makes sense. Empiricism is about what is true and what works. Often, what makes sense, what ought to be so, isn’t so and doesn’t work. And what is so and works doesn’t make sense.
It makes no sense that the earth should move around the sun rather than the other way around. And yet it moves. This is why rational basis review should not be based on judges’ convictions about what makes rational sense, but take experience and human limitations into account. As Justice Holmes put it very well, the life of the law has been experience, not logic.
Well stated.
OCCUPATIONAL DISABILITY: DOCTRINAIRE AND WHOLLY IMPRACTICAL
Very good to have this kind of contribution, adding a different perspective. As I see it (coming from the social sciences but being able to appreciate how American lawyers think ... or at least trying to), the problem here is legal scholars and jurists taking over the policymaking that should be happening in the political sphere, which is not their forte, no matter how brilliant their minds and work products in their own profession, whether advocacy or jurisprudence. And if advocacy, it's almost always on behalf of a client or favored constituency, rather than the general good, with an out-come oriented objective and pecuniary interest necessarily built into the advocacy.
Tort liability law (state law common-law doctrine/precedent) is obviously a form of indirect "state" regulation, but the tort litigation is always backward-looking and case-based, the key question being who to fault and make pay for damage(s) already done and sustained in a particular incident. That itself is not a rational way to promote - say - customers' safety in retail establishments as a general desideratum and finding the best combination of means to accomplish that objective, which will be one of many in competition with it.
Further, many harms suffered won't even become a tort cases when there is no reasonable expectation of collecting (even if civil legal liability would be easy to establish), and hence no incentive for an attorney/law firm to take the case on a contingent fee basis. As a result, the trial court caseload (PI, premises liability, and various subtypes) in a particular geographic jurisdiction is not going to be representative of entire population of injuries/harms suffered, or extent of victimization broadly speaking. So even when the litigation records/judgments are downloaded en masse from a court system server (as opposed to the limited selection of trial court orders that might available via WestLaw and other private data providers), that will be a biased sample. Not to mention limiting a study of cases on appeal. Those will highly preponderate to high-dollar and deep-pocket cases.
PROPHYLAXIS ANYONE? ... DYNAMIC POPULATION RESPONSE TO CHANGE IN LAW?
Similar caselaw-vs-policy problem with the abortion issue. Much talk about doctrine, precedent, and staring decisively or taking a new look at pertinent legal concepts; virtually no talk about doing a better job (her&him at the individual and in terms of policies/programs at the community level) preventing unwanted pregnancies in the first instance. No acknowledgement of what should be obvious: that folks have the ability to adjust their coital conduct, if not their sexual behavior more generally, to a more restrictive abortion regime, and thereby reduce the posited "need" for a convenient and cheap hometown abortion. And that public policies can be fashioned to promote better contraception. Instead, the "need" for abortion is taken as immutable. The rights talk trumps a sensible and practical approach to reducing the incidence of undesired pregnancies through appropriate measures earlier in the causal chain.
Try do a word frequency count for 'contraception' or 'condom' in the abortion news coverage and commentary and set the numerical results in relation to the general discourse vocabulary regading SB8 and Dobbs.
Regarding compromise (where doctrine-constricted minds perceive none as possible), see the NYT article yesterday offering a comparative (cross-national) view of abortion regimes, noting that generally the policy reflects legislative compromise elsewhere (sometimes even referendum, though not mentioned), and the US is an outlier.
Alas, the legal intelligentsia in the U.S. is boxed into their patterns of thinking and their penchant toward absolutism.
If you reject that charge and pride yourself of an open mind on this matter, you might wish the read the several amicus curiae briefs in Dobbs that add a comparative (European) perspective, including at least on abortion-related rulings under the European Court on Human Rights.
Also of interest -- to broaden the discourse space and enhance diversity in the argumentation -- would a discussion of the Kelsen-type models of *abstract judicial review* in other countries, since so much in relation to SB8 is about case & controversy, standing to sue, and other procedural impediments to bring a constitutional challenge and procure an authoritative adjudication.
And perhaps "advisory opinions" wouldn't be not such a bad thing after all. Especially in situations where there is considerable uncertainty about what the law is, or will soon be.
Which incidentally is also a problem with tort law on the edges: those affected and governed by it only learn at the backend of the litigation what the law was when in incident happened and how it applied to the collection of specific facts that made it into the court record as evidence.
Here we have a distinction between nuisance, which is subject to a balancing test, and trespass, which is not. I remember a lawsuit against a golf course because golfers were hitting golf balls onto a neighbor's property. The neighbor had a legal right to exclude all golf balls from her property even though I do not have a legal right to exclude all noise from my neighbor's party.
The analogy is not exact because the golf course intends for golf balls to fly through the air while the abortion clinic does not intend molotov cocktails to fly through the air. (And now I'm remembering the old SNL skit featuring Kevin Nealon as "Frank Gannon P.I. P.I.": https://snltranscripts.jt.org/91/91tgannon.phtml)
John,
Assume the clinic located to the area, which happened to be next door to his x-wife's new home, because he did intend for "golf balls to fly" if you will. The clinic is run straight up and the owner does not actively encourage nuisance type behavior, but a nuisance it is nonetheless. The owner is a passive owner and is never actually, himself, at the clinic.
How would the above injection of intent change your analysis, if at all?
Can x legitimately sue?
If you say yes, then intent matters, and the question becomes does something approximating intent, "e.g. conscious indifference to consequences which are almost certain to result", count also.
Marc
Did anyone else find this extremely disturbing:
“(For an overseas zoning law analog, consider the Australian decision upholding a refusal to allow a building permit for a synagogue because it could be a terrorist target, given "[t]he threat situation with respect to Jewish communities around the world and Australia.")”
I mean the case, not using it as an example. Is this not giving in to terrorists?
Indeed it is giving in to terrorists.
No, it's anti-Semites using giving into terrorists as an excuse.
DOWN UNDER
Ok, so let's all be appropriately outraged about the antipodes. That accomplished, what does it add to discussion of U.S. tort law? As a hypothetical? Could or would it happen here?
OPAQUE AREOLA COVERAGE ESTABLISHMENTS CLOSER TO HOME
It would seem that the zoning (by whaterver name) of SOBs and related ordinances in Texas would make better fodder to balance out the rather incendiary invocation of abortion-clinic arsonism (not to mention bombing). There has been considerable litigation of various aspect of this legal though controversial service industry, including secondary neighborhood effects.
Also, in statistical terms, it's probably fair to say that restaurants and gas stations are worse as "attractive nuisances" for violent crime than abortion clinics. Not to mention places were people drink and get trigger-happy in the parking lot: bars & nite clubs. Houston, we do indeed have a problem.
The other consideration is this: What is the proportion of peaceful pro-life "sidewalk counselors" to abortion-clinic arsonists/bombers to justify the analogy in the reasoning concerning general propositions? And as long as they are peaceful and respect the congressionally or judicially set perimeter proscription, how are these "ideologically motivated individuals" not exercising a right expressly protected by the U. S. Constitution.
How does expressing support for protection/saving of fetal life equate to a robber threating to take a life if money is not handed over?
There may, of course, be instances where abortion protesters stage a sit-in, i.e. commit trespass and are forcibly ejected/arrested. As for that group of scofflaws, wouldn't it seem that the comparison would be more appropriate with lunch-counter sitters protesting then-extant law in a prior era, as opposed to armed robbers issuing money-or-your-life demands?
See, e.g., Operation Rescue-National v. Planned Parenthood of Houston and Southeast Texas, Inc., 975 S.W.2d 546 (Tex. 1998).
https://scholar.google.com/scholar?scidkt=6338751565092361160&as_sdt=2&hl=en
"A landowner creates an actionable private "nuisance" for neighbors if it foreseeably..."
The landowner is a carbon life form. Ergo, s/it/he or she/
David Cary Hart: I expect that most landowners that are likely to be sued for nuisance on such a theory are corporations or other such business associations. Those are generally referred to in American legal writing as "it."
THE NEUTERED JUDICARY. Believe it or not: Judges are "its" too, at least in Texas. Even in mandamus actions where it's not the "court" that gets reversed, but a particular judge who is the respondent and gets mandamussed by the higher court (panel), or not, as the case might be.
I think the antecedent of "it" is "nuisance".
A business is held liable for the effects of the acts of criminals. That's crazy. It also violates the Fifth Amendment Procedural Due Process right to a fair hearing. You lawyers are nuts.
Maybe a little OT but here goes.
As a life long resident of Florida I have lived in many places with swimming pools including my present condo. While a double edged sword it is across the street from a high school. After several complaints from home owners we wound up putting a fence around the pool to restrict entry of high school students/others who started using the pool. This was quickly followed by a much more restrictive fence and more secure gate first with Medico keys and then with key cards since the keys were being duplicated not to mention the chain link fence allowed determined students/others to simply climb over the fence.
This was on legal advice from our insurance company since Florida has deemed pools as 'invitational hazards' that invite folks, especially kids, to risk drowning. As a kid in South Florida my Dad's house had a pool enclosed with screen (a popular option at the time) that someone (or someones) cut to gain entrance to swim. Seems a lawyer friend who also had a pool told my Dad he would still be liable for any injury suffered since the screen was not sufficient to deter entry.
No question in my mind trespass and probably breaking and entering charges would be justified but the perp would still be able to sue the pool owner. This is a link to law.
http://www.leg.state.fl.us/statutes/index.cfm?App_mode=Display_Statute&URL=0500-0599/0515/0515.html
Some location require pools to be fenced. One I know of requires a minimum 6'-0" high opaque fence. That not only keeps people out but screens the pool from casual view.
A condo I own has had problems with neighborhood kids using the pool, sometimes with the apparent permission of residents, even though the associate rules require an adult resident be present whenever children are in the pool. Security is an ongoing issue.
That law seems really extreme. A Connecticut homeowner told me he was required to put a low fence around his outside pool but state law did not make him liable for an attractive nuisance if somebody hopped the fence.
Interesting.
As I've said before, I'm not a lawyer. I do find the "logic" used in legal issues interesting. I'm curious about a paragraph in the article.
"If we were to hold that a legally-operated abortion clinic cannot even operate in a commercial office park zoned for medical practices without constituting a nuisance we would be, in effect, holding that such clinics cannot properly operate anywhere. As [amici curiae] correctly point out, such a holding could be used to expose a broad array of legal businesses and institutions to nuisance liability due to the fact that some find them controversial and some will protest their very existence."
Wouldn't this pertain to certain groups that want to hold protests or rallies, but are turned down for permits because other groups threaten trouble?
It does seem a form of "heckler's veto". I can imagine other types of businesses being protested as abortion clinics are for example gun stores or firing ranges.
Firing ranges do get protested and are sometimes forced to relocate before they actually get built. I haven't heard of any being sued by homeowners for insurance, probably because they aren't generally that close to homes.
Naval Air Station Whidbey Island was built in 1942 in a remote area in Washington State. Over the years the area built up around the Air Station. In the early 90's an upscale housing plan was built nearby. All of the sudden the aircraft were too noisy for the residents of the plan and they tried to force the Station's closure.
Is the concern noise or bullets? I live within earshot of a private firing range; I think it's just somebody's back yard but it is known to local police and they know how to respond when they get calls about gunfire in that part of town. It doesn't get enough use to be annoying. If I found a bullet on my land it would be another story.
Some random thoughts.
Land use restrictions have a long history in the US. In general it has been acceptable to restrict uses that are, or have the potential, to be a nuisance. Things like noise, smell, or heavy traffic are classic reasons to restrict how land is used to protect the value of close by land owners investment and their quality of life.
One of the unstated issues with abortion clinics is what I will call the economic issue. As a rule most medical doctors don't really like to become involved providing abortion services not so much for "moral" reasons but because they don't really provide much income and a lot of peeps wanting an abortion don't have adequate prenatal care and often don't really have the money to pay for the service. This is why abortion clinics not only have staffing problems but also don't generate revenue to cover operating expenses and depend on donations and government grants (don't get me started about how money is fungible). On the other hand if a woman has the ability to pay a doctor she can easily go to the doctor's office and get an abortion while not attracting attention.
Point is most women wanting an abortion also need financial assistance and often have other personal issues. So those attracted to abortion clinics are either poor or often noisy and annoying in protesting the clinics. Good reasons for close by neighbors to make an effort to get the clinic to locate somewhere else.
Point is that moral issues aside there are real reasons neighbors would not want to be close to an abortion clinic.